Skip to main content

Thank you for visiting nature.com. You are using a browser version with limited support for CSS. To obtain the best experience, we recommend you use a more up to date browser (or turn off compatibility mode in Internet Explorer). In the meantime, to ensure continued support, we are displaying the site without styles and JavaScript.

  • Article
  • Published:

Individual risk attitudes arise from noise in neurocognitive magnitude representations

Abstract

Humans are generally risk averse, preferring smaller certain over larger uncertain outcomes. Economic theories usually explain this by assuming concave utility functions. Here, we provide evidence that risk aversion can also arise from relative underestimation of larger monetary payoffs, a perceptual bias rooted in the noisy logarithmic coding of numerical magnitudes. We confirmed this with psychophysics and functional magnetic resonance imaging, by measuring behavioural and neural acuity of magnitude representations during a magnitude perception task and relating these measures to risk attitudes during separate risky financial decisions. Computational modelling indicated that participants use similar mental magnitude representations in both tasks, with correlated precision across perceptual and risky choices. Participants with more precise magnitude representations in parietal cortex showed less variable behaviour and less risk aversion. Our results highlight that at least some individual characteristics of economic behaviour can reflect capacity limitations in perceptual processing rather than processes that assign subjective values to monetary outcomes.

This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution

Access options

Buy this article

Prices may be subject to local taxes which are calculated during checkout

Fig. 1: The NLC model, experimental model and behavioural results.
Fig. 2: Neural magnitude representations in parietal cortex.
Fig. 3: Domain-generality of scale invariance across perceptual and risky-choice tasks.
Fig. 4: Noise in mental magnitude representations is individually robust across different types of visual display of risky prospects.
Fig. 5: The precision of mental magnitude representations systematically relates to individual risk attitudes.
Fig. 6: Relationship between neural measures of the precision of magnitude representations and risk aversion.
Fig. 7: The mediating effect of behavioural magnitude precision reveals the association between neural magnitude precision and risk aversion.

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

The behavioural data used in Figs. 27 and Extended Data Figs. 24, 6, 8 and 9 are available at https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.7966313. The neuroimaging data are available at Open Neuro: https://openneuro.org/datasets/ds004259.

Code availability

The codes are available at https://doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.7966313.

References

  1. Rabin, M. & Thaler, R. H. Anomalies: risk aversion. J. Econ. Perspect. 15, 219–232 (2001).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Bruhin, A., Fehr-Duda, H. & Epper, T. Risk and rationality: uncovering heterogeneity in probability distortion. Econometrica 78, 1375–1412 (2010).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Kahneman, D. & Tversky, A. Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47, 263–292 (1979).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  4. Mosteller, F. & Nogee, P. An experimental measurement of utility. J. Political Econ. 59, 371–404 (1951).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Hey, J. D. Why we should not be silent about noise. Exp. Econ. 8, 325–345 (2005).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  6. Khaw, M. W., Li, Z. & Woodford, M. Cognitive imprecision and small-stakes risk aversion. Rev. Econ. Stud. 88, 1979–2013 (2021).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Wilcox, N. T. in Risk Aversion in Experiments Vol. 12 (eds Cox, J. C. & Harrison, G. W.) 197–292 (Emerald Group Publishing Ltd, 2008).

  8. Platt, M. L. & Huettel, S. A. Risky business: the neuroeconomics of decision making under uncertainty. Nat. Neurosci. 11, 398–403 (2008).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  9. Roitman, J. D. & Roitman, M. F. Risk-preference differentiates orbitofrontal cortex responses to freely chosen reward outcomes. Eur. J. Neurosci. 31, 1492–1500 (2010).

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  10. Spitmaan, M., Chu, E. & Soltani, A. Salience-driven value construction for adaptive choice under risk. J. Neurosci. 39, 5195–5209 (2019).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  11. Izard, V. & Dehaene, S. Calibrating the mental number line. Cognition 106, 1221–1247 (2008).

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  12. Nieder, A. & Miller, E. K. Coding of cognitive magnitude. Neuron 37, 149–157 (2003).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  13. Petzschner, F. H., Glasauer, S. & Stephan, K. E. A Bayesian perspective on magnitude estimation. Trends Cogn. Sci. 19, 285–293 (2015).

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  14. Nieder, A. & Dehaene, S. Representation of number in the brain. Annu Rev. Neurosci. 32, 185–208 (2009).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  15. Harvey, B. M. & Dumoulin, S. O. A network of topographic numerosity maps in human association cortex. Nat. Hum. Behav. 1, 1424–1434 (2017).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  16. Harvey, B. M., Fracasso, A., Petridou, N. & Dumoulin, S. O. Topographic representations of object size and relationships with numerosity reveal generalized quantity processing in human parietal cortex. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 112, 13525–13530 (2015).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  17. Piazza, M., Izard, V., Pinel, P., Le Bihan, D. & Dehaene, S. Tuning curves for approximate numerosity in the human intraparietal sulcus. Neuron 44, 547–555 (2004).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  18. Lasne, G., Piazza, M., Dehaene, S., Kleinschmidt, A. & Eger, E. Discriminability of numerosity-evoked fMRI activity patterns in human intra-parietal cortex reflects behavioral numerical acuity. Cortex 114, 90–101 (2019).

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  19. Frydman, C. & Jin, L. J. Efficient coding and risky choice. Q. J. Econ. 137, 161–213 (2022).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Woodford, M. Modeling imprecision in perception, valuation, and choice. Annu. Rev. Econ. 12, 579–601 (2020).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Rabin, M. Risk aversion and expected-utility theory: a calibration theorem. Econometrica 68, 1281–1292 (2000).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Pouget, A., Beck, J. M., Ma, W. J. & Latham, P. E. Probabilistic brains: knowns and unknowns. Nat. Neurosci. 16, 1170–1178 (2013).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  23. Harvey, B. M., Klein, B. P., Petridou, N. & Dumoulin, S. O. Topographic representation of numerosity in the human parietal cortex. Science 341, 1123–1126 (2013).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  24. van Bergen, R. S., Ji Ma, W., Pratte, M. S. & Jehee, J. F. M. Sensory uncertainty decoded from visual cortex predicts behavior. Nat. Neurosci. 18, 1728–1730 (2015).

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  25. Dehaene, S. The neural basis of the Weber–Fechner law: a logarithmic mental number line. Trends Cogn. Sci. 7, 145–147 (2003).

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  26. Kersey, A. J. & Cantlon, J. F. Neural tuning to numerosity relates to perceptual tuning in 3–6-year-old children. J. Neurosci. 37, 512–522 (2017).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  27. Nieder, A., Freedman, D. J. & Miller, E. K. Representation of the quantity of visual items in the primate prefrontal cortex. Science 297, 1708–1711 (2002).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  28. van Bergen, R. S. & Jehee, J. F. M. Probabilistic representation in human visual cortex reflects uncertainty in serial decisions. J. Neurosci. 39, 8164–8176 (2019).

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  29. Wichmann, F. A. & Hill, N. J. The psychometric function: I. fitting, sampling, and goodness of fit. Percept. Psychophys. 63, 1293–1313 (2001).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  30. Snoek, L., Miletić, S. & Scholte, H. S. How to control for confounds in decoding analyses of neuroimaging data. Neuroimage 184, 741–760 (2019).

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  31. Olschewski, S., Rieskamp, J. & Scheibehenne, B. Taxing cognitive capacities reduces choice consistency rather than preference: a model-based test. J. Exp. Psychol. Gen. 147, 462–484 (2018).

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  32. Gai, P. & Vause, N. Risk appetite: concept and measurement. Financial Stab. Rev. 17, 127–136 (2004).

    Google Scholar 

  33. Kacelnik, A. & Brito e Abreu, F. Risky choice and Weber’s law. J. Theor. Biol. 194, 289–298 (1998).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  34. Wei, X.-X. & Stocker, A. A. A Bayesian observer model constrained by efficient coding can explain ‘anti-Bayesian’ percepts. Nat. Neurosci. 18, 1509–1517 (2015).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  35. Polanía, R., Krajbich, I., Grueschow, M. & Ruff, C. C. Neural oscillations and synchronization differentially support evidence accumulation in perceptual and value-based decision making. Neuron 82, 709–720 (2014).

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  36. Pardo-Vazquez, J. L. et al. The mechanistic foundation of Weber’s law. Nat. Neurosci. 22, 1493–1502 (2019).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  37. Harvey, B. M., Dumoulin, S. O., Fracasso, A. & Paul, J. M. A network of topographic maps in human association cortex hierarchically transforms visual timing-selective responses. Curr. Biol. 30, 1424–1434 (2020).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  38. Chew, B. et al. Endogenous fluctuations in the dopaminergic midbrain drive behavioral choice variability. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 116, 18732–18737 (2019).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  39. Preuschoff, K., Quartz, S. R. & Bossaerts, P. Human insula activation reflects risk prediction errors as well as risk. J. Neurosci. 28, 2745–2752 (2008).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  40. Sacré, P. et al. Risk-taking bias in human decision-making is encoded via a right–left brain push–pull system. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 116, 1404–1413 (2019).

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  41. Shi, W., Ballesta, S. & Padoa-Schioppa, C. Neuronal origins of reduced accuracy and biases in economic choices under sequential offers. eLife 11, e75910 (2022).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  42. Padoa-Schioppa, C. Neuronal origins of choice variability in economic decisions. Neuron 80, 1322–1336 (2013).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  43. Heilbronner, S. R. & Hayden, B. Y. Contextual factors explain risk-seeking preferences in rhesus monkeys. Front Neurosci. 7, 7 (2013).

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  44. Eisenreich, B. R., Hayden, B. Y. & Zimmermann, J. Macaques are risk-averse in a freely moving foraging task. Sci. Rep. 9, 15091 (2019).

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  45. Juechems, K., Balaguer, J., Ruz, M. & Summerfield, C. Ventromedial prefrontal cortex encodes a latent estimate of cumulative reward. Neuron 93, 705–714.e4 (2017).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  46. Kusev, P. et al. Understanding risky behavior: the influence of cognitive, emotional and hormonal factors on decision-making under risk. Front. Psychol. 8, 102 (2017).

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  47. Dehaene, S. & Cohen, L. Two mental calculation systems: a case study of severe acalculia with preserved approximation. Neuropsychologia 29, 1045–1074 (1991).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  48. Arsalidou, M. & Taylor, M. J. Is 2 + 2 = 4? Meta-analyses of brain areas needed for numbers and calculations. Neuroimage 54, 2382–2393 (2011).

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  49. Heng, J. A., Woodford, M. & Polania, R. Efficient sampling and noisy decisions. eLife 9, e54962 (2020).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  50. Polanía, R., Woodford, M. & Ruff, C. C. Efficient coding of subjective value. Nat. Neurosci. 22, 134–142 (2019).

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  51. Krajbich, I., Armel, C. & Rangel, A. Visual fixations and the computation and comparison of value in simple choice. Nat. Neurosci. 13, 1292–1298 (2010).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  52. Caplin, A. & Dean, M. in Neuroeconomics (eds Glimcher, P. W. et al.) 21–31 (Elsevier, 2009).

  53. Gul, F. & Pesendorfer, W. in The Foundations of Positive and Normative Economics (eds Caplin, A. & Schotter, A.) 2–40 (Oxford Univ. Press, 2008).

  54. He, L., Zhao, W. J. & Bhatia, S. An ontology of decision models. Psychol. Rev. 129, 49–72 (2022).

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  55. Haefner, R. M., Gerwinn, S., Macke, J. H. & Bethge, M. Inferring decoding strategies from choice probabilities in the presence of correlated variability. Nat. Neurosci. 16, 235–242 (2013).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  56. Furman, M. & Wang, X.-J. Similarity effect and optimal control of multiple-choice decision making. Neuron 60, 1153–1168 (2008).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  57. Behrens, T. E. J. et al. What is a cognitive map? Organizing knowledge for flexible behavior. Neuron 100, 490–509 (2018).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  58. Lyons, I. M., Ansari, D. & Beilock, S. L. Qualitatively different coding of symbolic and nonsymbolic numbers in the human brain. Hum. Brain Mapp. 36, 475–488 (2015).

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  59. Price, G. R., Holloway, I., Räsänen, P., Vesterinen, M. & Ansari, D. Impaired parietal magnitude processing in developmental dyscalculia. Curr. Biol. 17, R1042–R1043 (2007).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  60. Specker, S., Carlson, G., Christenson, G. & Marcotte, M. Impulse control disorders and attention deficit disorder in pathological gamblers. Ann. Clin. Psychiatry 7, 175–179 (1995).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  61. Engelmann, J. B., Meyer, F., Fehr, E. & Ruff, C. C. Anticipatory anxiety disrupts neural valuation during risky choice. J. Neurosci. 35, 3085–3099 (2015).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  62. Tymula, A., Rosenberg Belmaker, L. A., Ruderman, L., Glimcher, P. W. & Levy, I. Like cognitive function, decision making across the life span shows profound age-related changes. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 110, 17143–17148 (2013).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  63. Dillon, M. R., Kannan, H., Dean, J. T., Spelke, E. S. & Duflo, E. Cognitive science in the field: a preschool intervention durably enhances intuitive but not formal mathematics. Science 357, 47–55 (2017).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  64. Skagerlund, K., Lind, T., Strömbäck, C., Tinghög, G. & Västfjäll, D. Financial literacy and the role of numeracy—how individuals’ attitude and affinity with numbers influence financial literacy. J. Behav. Exp. Econ. 74, 18–25 (2018).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  65. Apesteguia, J. & Ballester, M. A. Monotone stochastic choice models: the case of risk and time preferences. J. Political Econ. 126, 74–106 (2018).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  66. Nilsson, H., Rieskamp, J. & Wagenmakers, E.-J. Hierarchical Bayesian parameter estimation for cumulative prospect theory. J. Math. Psychol. 55, 84–93 (2011).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  67. Bordalo, P., Gennaioli, N. & Shleifer, A. Salience theory of choice under risk. Q. J. Econ. 127, 1243–1285 (2012).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  68. Kruschke, J. Doing Bayesian Data Analysis: A Tutorial with R, JAGS, and STAN (Academic Press, 2015).

  69. Plummer, M. JAGS: a program for analysis of Bayesian graphical models using Gibbs sampling. In Proc. 3rd International Workshop on Distributed Statistical Computing 124, 1–10 (2003).

    Google Scholar 

  70. Meyer, R. Deviance information criterion (DIC) in Wiley StatsRef: Statistics Reference Online (Wiley, 2016); https://doi.org/10.1002/9781118445112.stat07878

  71. Esteban, O. et al. fMRIPrep: a robust preprocessing pipeline for functional MRI. Nat. Methods 16, 111–116 (2019).

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  72. Dumoulin, S. O. & Wandell, B. A. Population receptive field estimates in human visual cortex. Neuroimage 39, 647–660 (2008).

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to C. Schnyder, K. Treiber and M. Moisa at the Zurich Center for Neuroeconomics for their excellent assistance in recruitment and participant facilitation. This project has received funding from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme (grant agreement no. 725355, ERC consolidator grant BRAINCODES). M.B.G. was funded by the Marlene Porsche Graduate School in Neuroeconomics and C.C.R. received funding from the University Research Priority Program ‘Adaptive Brain Circuits in Development and Learning’ (grant no. URPP AdaBD) at the University of Zurich and the Swiss National Science Foundation (grant no. 100019L-173248). G.D.H. was funded by the Dutch Research Council NWO (Rubicon grant no. 019.183SG.017/8O3B). We are thankful for the relevant feedback that we received during the 2019 Sloan-NOMIS Workshop for the Attentional and Perceptual Foundations of Economic Behavior as well as the 2020 virtual Annual Meeting of the Society for Neuroeconomics. The funders had no role in the study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish or preparation of the manuscript.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

All authors developed the experimental design and procedures, and contributed to the analysis pipeline of the behavioural data. M.B.G. collected the data. M.B.G. and G.D.H. analysed the data. G.D.H. set up the analysis pipeline for the fMRI decoding analysis. M.B.G., G.D.H. and C.C.R. wrote and revised the manuscript, with input from M.G., R.P. and M.W.

Corresponding authors

Correspondence to Miguel Barretto-García or Christian C. Ruff.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Peer review

Peer review information

Nature Human Behaviour thanks Colin Camerer, Stefan Glasauer, Ivan Grahek and the other, anonymous, reviewer(s) for their contribution to the peer review of this work. Peer reviewer reports are available.

Additional information

Publisher’s note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Extended data

Extended Data Fig. 1 Model comparison between the NLC model and competing economic choice models.

DIC difference between the best model (the NLC model in all cases) and the competing economic choice models: constant relative risk aversion (CRRA), cumulative prospect theory (CPT), and salience theory (ST) in both (a) non-symbolic and (b) symbolic visual display formats. We fitted each of these economic choice models using the Logit (1) and Probit (2) model specifications.

Extended Data Fig. 2 Individual behavioural differences.

Observed choice probabilities of each individual participant were plotted against the log-ratio of monetary offers or magnitudes for (a) non-symbolic risky choice (orange), (b) symbolic risky choice (blue), and (c) perceptual magnitudes (purple). The NLC model was used to fit the psychometric curves of each individual (black solid line). The numbers above each plot denotes participant ID.

Extended Data Fig. 3 Individual differences in choices for extreme offer magnitudes.

Histograms of choice probabilities (across subjects) for coin clouds (left, purple) or risky offers in nonsymbolic (middle, orange) and symbolic (right, blue) presentation formats, for trials with (a) the highest and (b) lowest magnitudes/offers. The distributions are drawn from the extreme value points of the individual choice data in Extended Data Fig. 2. The more the distributions are skewed towards 1 (for a) and 0 (for b), the less evidence for lapses across individual subjects.

Extended Data Fig. 4 The NLC model accounts for perceptual bias and risk aversion arising from noisy magnitude representations.

(a) Choice probabilities plotted in linear (left) and logarithmic (right) space as the ratio of the second- and first-coin cloud magnitudes (perceptual task, red) or risky and sure payoffs (risky-choice task, blue). The NLC model predicts that the indifference point in the perceptual task is \({\theta }_{{perceptual}}\approx 1\) regardless of noisy magnitude representations while \({\theta }_{{risky}}\) in risky choice depends on magnitude noise. The indifference point—the ratio of magnitudes where the individual is indifferent between \(X\) or \(C\), expressed as \(\theta ={\left(\frac{1}{p}\right)}^{\frac{1}{\beta }}\)—is represented as the intersection of the black horizontal dashed line and the points of the psychometric curve. In perceptual magnitude, there is no outcome uncertainty (\(p=1\)) in both dot clouds; hence, \({\theta }_{{perceptual}}\approx 1\) regardless of whether magnitude representations are noisy (\(\beta < 0\) and \(\nu > 0\), solid pink psychometric curve) or not (\(\beta =1\) and \(\nu =0\), dashed pink stepwise function). This implies that the intercept is \({\delta }_{{perceptual}}\approx 0\). In risky choice, outcome probability is fixed at \(p=0.55\) for the risky payoff. In the absence of noise (\(\beta =1\) and \(\nu =0\)), the indifference point reflects the relative value of payoffs, \({\theta }_{{risky}}=\frac{X}{C}=\frac{1}{0.55}\) (intersection of the black dashed horizontal line and blue dashed stepwise function). With magnitude noise (\(\beta < 1\) and \(\nu > 0\)), \({\theta }_{{risky}}\) is larger than risk-neutral indifference of \(\frac{1}{0.55}\), \({{\theta }_{{risky}}=\left(\frac{1}{0.55}\right)}^{\frac{1}{\beta }} > \frac{1}{0.55}\) (intersection of the black dashed horizontal line and blue solid psychometric curve). This is reflected as a shift of the psychometric curve to the right relative to the risk-neutral stepwise function. Risk aversion is quantified as the magnitude of the rightward shift of the psychometric function compared to the risk-neutral indifference point, \({\theta }_{{risky}}=\frac{1}{0.55}\). Risk-neutral probability, \({\pi }_{{risky}}\), is the reciprocal of the indifference point, \({\pi }_{{risky}}={0.55}^{\frac{1}{\beta }}\). (b) Decreasing the width of the prior, \(\sigma\), shifts the psychometric curve to the right, and thus increases risk aversion. The indifference point can also be expressed as \(\theta ={\left(\frac{1}{p}\right)}^{\frac{1}{\beta }}={\left(\frac{1}{p}\right)}^{\frac{{\sigma }^{2}+{\nu }^{2}}{{\sigma }^{2}}}\) to explicitly show the link between \(\sigma\) and \(\theta\), and why decreasing the prior increases the indifference point and shifts the psychometric curve rightward. The psychometric curves are plotted in linear (left) and logarithmic (right) space and the different colours represent different prior widths.

Extended Data Fig. 5 Behavioural effects of the presentation format of monetary magnitudes.

(a) Population posterior distributions of the (a, b) intercept, , as well as (c, d) the indifference point, θ, for both (a,c) perceptual magnitude and (b, d) risky choice tasks. The intercept during perceptual magnitude is no different from zero (indicated here by the vertical dashed line) while it is significantly larger than zero during risky choice in both visual displays. Similarly, the indifference point in perceptual magnitude is no different from one while in risky choice, it is significantly larger than the threshold, \(\frac{1}{0.55}\) (the vertical dashed line). Distributions in pink represent data from the perceptual magnitude task, in blue represent data from risky symbolic payoffs, and in yellow-orange for risky nonsymbolic payoffs. One-sided Bayesian ‘p-values’ were calculated: The light pink-shaded mass of the highest density interval (HDI) covers 95% of the posterior distribution while the dark-shaded tail-ends represent the most extreme 5% probability mass of the posterior distribution. Bayesian comparison between posteriors reveal that the posterior distribution is significantly different from zero (represented here as a vertical dashed line) if the light-shaded mass does not cross zero. (e) Individual measures of the indifference point for nonsymbolic and symbolic payoffs are positively correlated (n = 62). The shaded area around the regression line represents 95% confidence intervals. The black dashed line represents the identity line. p-values were estimated from one-sided Pearson correlations.

Extended Data Fig. 6 Behavioural and neural measures of representation acuity and risky choice variability.

(a) The estimated precision of mental magnitude representations employed for the perceptual task, γperceptual, and the risky decision-making task, γsymbolic and γnonsymbolic, are related (n = 64), for both types of visual displays, as predicted by the NLC model. The diagonal dashed line represents the identity line. Shaded area are error bands corresponding to 95% confidence interval for the regression line. p-values were estimated from one-sided Pearson correlations. (b) Group-level posterior distributions of non-symbolic risk (γnonsymbolic, orange), symbolic risk (γsymbolic, blue), and perceptual magnitude (γperceptual, pink) precision. Top plots the posterior distributions while the bottom plots are distributions of differences between precision measurements (in pink). One-sided Bayesian ‘p-values’ were calculated: The light-shaded mass of the highest density interval (HDI) covers 95% of the posterior distribution while the dark-shaded tail-ends represent 5% of the posterior distribution. The vertical dashed line represents zero. (c) The correlations between the neural precision parameter and the risky choice precision parameter γ were not statistically significant (n = 64), but in the hypothesised direction: the higher the neural precision, the less variable the behaviour. (d) Neural diminishing sensitivity was significantly correlated with the risky choice precision parameter γ (n = 64) for the non-symbolic presentation format and marginally significant for the symbolic presentation format. The shaded area around the regression line represents 95% confidence intervals. p-values were estimated from one-sided Pearson correlations.

Extended Data Fig. 7 Individual risk measures relate systematically to choice accuracy in the perceptual task.

(a) Raw measures of individual perceptual choice accuracy and the frequency of choosing the risky payoff (n = 64) are related across all visual displays. Perceptual accuracy is also related (n = 64) to the more precise model-defined measurements of (b) the estimated precision of potential payoffs and (c) the index of risk aversion across visual display types. (d) These correlations reflect that magnitude precision in the perceptual task relates strongly to choice accuracy (but is not affected by response biases and the response noise contained in pure choice accuracy measures). Circular dots represent subjects. The shaded area around the regression line represents 95% confidence intervals. p-values were estimated from one-sided Pearson correlations.

Extended Data Fig. 8 Perceptual choice precision mediates the association between neural precision and risky choice precision.

(a) The effect of neural precision on risky choice precision for the task using non-symbolic numbers (n = 64) is mediated by perceptual choice variability. There is no significant direct or total effect. (b) The effect of neural precision on risky choice precision for the task using symbolic presentation format is mediated by perceptual choice variability. There is no significant direct or total effect. The effect of neural diminishing sensitivity on risky choice precision for the task using (c) non-symbolic numbers is mediated by perceptual choice precision, but less so for (d) symbolic numbers. One-sided Bayesian ‘p-values’ were calculated using hierarchical Bayesian mediation analysis (see Methods and Extended Data Fig. 9b).

Extended Data Fig. 9 Hierarchical Bayesian models.

Graphical representations of the hierarchical Bayesian (a) noisy logarithmic coding model and (b) mediation analysis. Clear circles represent latent variables while filled circles are observed variables, such as trialwise choice (rcsi) data, subject-wise behavioural and neural measurements (yj), and numerosity/payoff inputs (X,C). See Supplementary Note for more details.

Supplementary information

Supplementary Information

Supplementary Tables 1–3, Methods and Note.

Reporting Summary

Peer Review File

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Barretto-García, M., de Hollander, G., Grueschow, M. et al. Individual risk attitudes arise from noise in neurocognitive magnitude representations. Nat Hum Behav 7, 1551–1567 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1038/s41562-023-01643-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1038/s41562-023-01643-4

Search

Quick links

Nature Briefing

Sign up for the Nature Briefing newsletter — what matters in science, free to your inbox daily.

Get the most important science stories of the day, free in your inbox. Sign up for Nature Briefing