Main

There is broad scientific consensus that halting forest loss is required to tackle the dual global crises of climate change and biodiversity loss1,2. Notwithstanding their provision of multiple services, the contribution of forests in removing CO2 from the atmosphere and storing it in a long-term carbon sink carries a particularly high social (economic) value3, and scientific research has produced increasingly sophisticated methods to assess this value4. In the global effort to reach net zero by 2050, combatting forest loss remains a feature of governmental and private decarbonization initiatives, for example, the Race to Zero Campaign5,6 and the UNFCCC-REDD+ mechanism7,8 (Reducing Emissions from Deforestation and Forest Degradation and the Role of Conservation, Sustainable Management of Forests and Enhancement of Forest Carbon Stocks in Developing Countries). Analysing and assessing trends in forest losses is therefore of global social relevance, while identifying factors underlying these trends is a precondition to control the drivers of forest losses.

The effectiveness of policies and private financial incentives to reduce forest losses (for example, the REDD+ initiatives9 or payments for ecosystem services10) remains highly debated11. Tracing back the impacts of domestic policies and other influential factors on forest loss is challenging12. Commonly cited country-scale factors associated with trends in forest loss include market-based factors, such as demand for agricultural commodities13 or minerals14; governance-related factors (for example, command-and-control policies15, the rollout of land titles for communities16 or pre-election promises17); factors associated with social conflicts and crises (for example, armed conflicts18 or COVID-1919); and climate anomalies, such as El Niño20.

To associate trends in forest losses with specific factors, counterfactuals are needed to show what losses would have occurred under a reference scenario that excludes these factors21. Reference scenarios are critically important to identify and demonstrate the additionality of achieved emission reductions22. Avoiding forest losses represents a nature-based solution (as an initiative to achieve societal goals by working with nature23) to combat climate change. Additionality means that observed emission reductions would not have occurred under business-as-usual conditions24. In the absence of government intervention, market forces can either exacerbate or mitigate trends in forest loss. Mitigation would happen when land managers become increasingly satisfied with the economic outcome of their current land-use allocation and stop clearing forest, or when decreasing commodity prices lead them to reduce agricultural expansion25. Both trends would cause non-additional emission reductions. So far, counterfactual studies have mostly been constructed from empirical forest loss data by applying quasi-experimental statistical models (Supplementary Table 1). However, these approaches usually focus on a specific policy instrument, the effects of which are difficult to isolate empirically.

In light of this, our study presents a new simulation approach to derive counterfactual forest loss trajectories that are generalizable beyond the context of a specific policy instrument. We separate market-driven from non-market-driven forest losses: the former offer a counterfactual reference scenario, while the latter represent residual forest losses not driven by economic expectations. Our novel approach combines economic land-use allocation modelling, satisficing decision rules under the influence of future uncertainty and heterogeneous decision-makers borrowed from agent-based modelling26 (see Supplementary Table 1 for land-use modelling alternatives). Thus, our model assumes that (1) forest loss is largely driven by agricultural land transformation processes27, (2) land-use decision-makers probably seek satisficing (‘good-enough’) rather than maximal outcomes when accounting for uncertainty28 and (3) social processes underlying land-use allocation are driven by heterogeneous individual intentions29.

Our simulated counterfactual land-use allocation decisions build on market data and agricultural productivities from 1990–2019. We simulate a total of 9 million random profit scenarios of heterogeneous farmer groups (Fig. 1) to derive expected forest losses for three large contributors to global forest loss: Brazil, the Democratic Republic (DR) of Congo and Indonesia30 (Supplementary Fig. 3). This economic model accounts for the private incentives to convert forest to different land-use types (profits and uncertainties) and thus provides market-oriented counterfactuals (Fig. 1).

Fig. 1: Model concept.
figure 1

Illustration of the market-oriented counterfactual modelling and assessment approach.

We address three main questions:

  1. 1.

    When do observed forest losses diverge considerably from those simulated by our economic model for the three selected countries?

  2. 2.

    What factors are likely to affect observed forest losses at the country scale and potentially explain reduced and excess forest losses compared with the market-based counterfactual forest loss?

  3. 3.

    What is the social economic value of avoided climate damages from reduced forest emissions?

The difference between our market-driven counterfactual model and the empirical forest loss data allows us to identify periods when forest loss is attributable to market forces (good alignment between our counterfactual and the empirical forest loss data), as well as periods where the forest cover change is likely attributable to additional non-market forces. While our counterfactual model does not offer clear attribution of single drivers and is not intended to evaluate the effectiveness of specific conservation policies, it can offer insights into which broad country-scale factors shape changes in the levels of forest losses based on temporal congruence17. These factors include armed conflicts, pre-election promises made by politicians, government changes, severe ENSO climate pressures (2015–2016) and command-and-control policies intended to reduce forest losses (Methods and Supplementary Methods 3).

One contribution of our innovative counterfactual approach is in estimating the social economic value associated with avoided deforestation, which is important for communicating the economic value of reducing forest losses. In climate economics, avoided climate damages through temporary cooling effects31—for example, by retaining instead of clearing carbon-rich forest—generate social economic value4. A useful concept for assessing this value is the social cost of carbon (SCC) (Box 1). Up to now, a frequently disregarded aspect of such valuations is the potential non-permanence of the achieved emission reductions4,31, which we consider here. We use this approach to estimate the social value of emission reductions achieved by avoiding tropical forest losses.

Market-driven counterfactual forest losses

Our counterfactual land-use allocation model (Fig. 1) identifies the forest losses that would probably have resulted from market-driven decisions in Brazil, DR Congo and Indonesia—that is, without the influence of policies to reduce deforestation and without other non-market drivers of forest losses.

The highest counterfactual deforestation rates (forest loss relative to total forest area) are predicted for Indonesia and the lowest for DR Congo (Fig. 2a). The average (and median) deforestation rates differ more widely among the three countries in the period 1990–1994 than in 2015–2019. Additionally, the range of simulated deforestation rates tends to decrease over time for Brazil and Indonesia (Supplementary Methods 7). The distribution of these rates follows a power-law relationship (Fig. 2b), which can also be observed in empirical analyses (for example, for deforestation patch sizes in ref. 32).

Fig. 2: Counterfactual deforestation rates.
figure 2

a, Boxplots (consisting of n = 9,000 simulated deforestation rates, each single estimate obtained from a mathematical programme considering 1,000 economic profit scenarios; details of the simulations can be found in Supplementary Methods 1) of deforestation rates. The x axis shows the start and end year of each 5 yr period. Solid vertical lines, median; crosses (x), arithmetic mean; lower and upper hinges, 25th and 75th percentiles; whiskers extend from the upper/lower hinge to the largest/smallest value no further from the hinge than 1.5 times the interquartile range. Data beyond the whiskers are ‘outliers’ and are plotted individually. b, The frequency distribution of the counterfactual deforestation rates follows a power-law relationship: N = 3,936 × \(10^{-0.88\times l_{\mathrm{class}}}\). lclass is the forest loss class.

To assess the quality of the predicted counterfactual forest cover losses, we conducted a series of statistical analyses and cross-study comparisons. Two independent counterfactual forest loss trajectories reveal similar results (Supplementary Fig. 1). The market-driven counterfactual forest losses show good agreement with observed forest losses. In a statistical comparison considering all three countries, market-driven forest losses predicted by our counterfactual model explain 59% of the variation of observed forest losses (Supplementary Fig. 2a). Controlling for periods coinciding with non-market factors (here, command-and-control policies, climate anomalies, armed conflicts and pre-election promises), statistical model predictions explain 75% of the variation in observed forest losses (Supplementary Table 2 and Fig. 2b). The time series of counterfactual forest losses (Supplementary Fig. 1) respond to periods with declining crop prices by predicting smaller forest losses, for example, when soybean prices decreased in Brazil from 2005 onwards (Fig. 3a) and palm oil prices fell in Indonesia from 2010 onwards (Fig. 3c).

Fig. 3: Observed and reference forest cover losses for the three selected countries.
figure 3

a, Brazil. b, DR Congo. c, Indonesia (see Methods and Supplementary Methods 1 for methodological details). Observed forest losses refer to tree cover losses obtained from Global Forest Watch. Forest losses from FAO Statistics are shown for comparison and were used for calibration (1990–1999) in the absence of remotely sensed data.

Non-market-driven forest losses

A general comparison suggests lower-than-expected forest losses (arising from non-market factors) of 11.1 million hectares overall (6.7 million hectares in Brazil, zero hectares in DR Congo and 4.4 million hectares in Indonesia) in two phases of deforestation reduction coinciding with command-and-control policies. This amounts to 11% of the reference forest losses between 2000–2019 in the three countries (Table 1). In contrast, in periods of higher-than-expected forest losses (coinciding with pre-election promises, armed conflicts or climate phenomena), forest losses exceed the counterfactual levels by a total of 11.3 million hectares (Table 1), fully offsetting the aggregate forest loss reduction periods across the three countries. The estimated emissions from the observed forest cover losses are 0.20 gigatonnes CO2 higher than the expected emissions (equivalent to a 0.4% increase relative to the emissions from expected forest losses).

Table 1 Periods of change in trends of forest losses according to literature and differences from our market-driven counterfactual simulations

Reduced and excess forest loss

For Brazil, deviations of the observed from counterfactual forest losses indicate one reduction period (coinciding with command-and-control policies) and one excess period of forest loss (coinciding with climate anomalies) (Fig. 3a). Mainly lower-than-expected forest cover losses are identified from 2004 to 2012 in a reduction phase of forest loss (Fig. 4a). From 2012 onwards, the modelled forest losses mimic the dynamics of observed forest losses well, suggesting a period of mainly market-oriented land-use decisions. The year 2016 marks a deforestation spike and a pronounced excess phase of deforestation with additional forest losses (Fig. 4a). In sum, a net saving of forest area of 3.4 million hectares remains (or 7.3 million hectares ignoring the extensive wildfire forest losses in 2016 and 2017), when subtracting excess forest losses from achieved reductions of forest losses (6%, or 12% without wildfire losses, of the 2000–2019 reference level of forest losses).

Fig. 4: Differences in observed and couterfactual forest losses and related changes in CO2 emissions.
figure 4

ac, Differences between observed and counterfactual forest losses in documented reduction and excess periods of forest loss for Brazil (a), DR Congo (b) and Indonesia (c) (Table 1). df, The corresponding estimated changes in CO2 emissions together with the associated impact on their social value in a given year. The thin bars in 2015 and 2016 for Indonesia and Brazil, respectively, include emissions by wildfire, which we however excluded from the calculation of the social value of emission reductions.

For DR Congo, we obtain an overestimation of forest losses from 2001 to 2005 compared with observed forest losses, but a good alignment with FAO-reported forest losses used for calibration (in the absence of remotely sensed information from 1990–1999) (Fig. 3b). However, our model does not mirror the observed forest losses from 2012 onwards. The identified deviations mark an excess phase of deforestation (Fig. 4b), suggesting higher-than-expected forest losses (Table 1) (coinciding with armed conflicts). The excess forest loss reaches 3.8 million hectares, some 29% of the reference level of forest losses (2000–2019).

In Indonesia, we identify both reduction (coinciding with command-and-control policies) and excess periods of forest losses (coinciding with pre-election promises). In the reduction period, observed forest losses sharply decrease in the period 2000–2005 (Fig. 4c). From 2006 to 2010, we again obtain a good agreement between observed and reference forest losses, pointing to a market-oriented period. Observed forest losses tend to exceed modelled forest losses from 2011 onwards, leading to an excess phase of forest loss (Fig. 4c). The net effect of reduction and excess phases is a less-than-expected forest loss of 0.12 million hectares, which is 0.5% of the reference level of forest losses (2000–2019). Excluding the wildfire forest losses in Indonesia in 2016 leads to a net reduction of forest losses by 0.86 million hectares (3% of the reference level of forest losses).

The social value of avoided emissions

The trend changes in forest losses for Brazil (2004–2012) and Indonesia (2000–2005) (Fig. 4d,f) have probably caused climate cooling effects, achieved by a reduction of CO2 emissions (see ref. 4,31 for confirming such effects) coinciding with command-and-control policies. Such cooling effects are partly offset by later climate warming effects through increased emissions in Indonesia, coinciding with pre-election promises. The estimated cumulative avoided or increased CO2 emissions from 2000–2019, which we used for our social valuation approach (Methods equation (5) and Supplementary Methods 4), range between +2.757 avoided (Brazil, enhanced carbon storage) and −1.573 additional gigatonnes CO2 (DR Congo, reduced carbon storage) (Fig. 4 and Table 2). For our social value calculation, we use conservative SCC33,34 growing from US$30.1 (2000) to US$44.1 per tonne CO2 emission (2019) (2015 US$; see Supplementary Table 9). We exclude the emissions from natural wildfires occurring in association with climate anomalies in Brazil and Indonesia (2016–2017), which are probably mainly natural phenomena.

Table 2 Social value of emission trends under various assumptions and land-opportunity costs for land managers

Benefits (reductions of emissions) and costs (increases of emissions) impact the social value of the trends of forest losses in the three countries. The social value of changes to forest losses from non-market forces considers the benefits of emission reductions and the costs of emissions measured from the perspective of 2000 (Fig. 4d–f). Yet the timing of these benefits and costs matters because their associated damages are discounted as in the case of the SCC4. We use a constant discount rate to convert all costs and benefits to their present value in 2019 (Methods, equations (3) and (5)). Our method penalizes temporary warming (increased damages) and values temporary cooling31 (avoided damages). For example, CO2 not emitted into the atmosphere by reducing forest losses in 2000 avoids social costs of damages over 20 yr, even when released into the atmosphere in 2019.

This social value of the non-market emission effects (Methods equation (5)) is then +US$133.8 and +US$36.7 billion in Brazil and Indonesia, respectively (see Table 2), but emission trends in DR Congo contribute negatively to the social value with −US$71.3 billion, if we consider the CO2 emission changes as permanent from 2020 onwards.

Accounting for possible non-permanence of emission changes after 2019 by assuming a 1% likelihood per year that the climate beneficial (Brazil and Indonesia) or adverse effect (DR Congo) reverses (see Methods, equation (5)) alters the value of the emission reduction, depending on how much CO2 emissions are cumulatively avoided or added by the trend changes until 2019 (Table 2). The reduction of the social value is stronger in Brazil (−46%), where higher avoided CO2 emissions have accumulated, than in Indonesia (−29%). However, the remaining climate benefits are still strongest in Brazil (social value of emission reduction accounting for non-permanence +US$72.1 billion).

Reducing forest losses comes with a cost for land managers who forgo land-use benefits otherwise obtained from expanding agricultural land or timber plantations at the cost of tropical forest. We calculate the accumulated value of the forgone profits to land managers as present values in 2019 (Methods, equation (8)), which we also use as reference year for the social value calculation. These costs are moderate and much lower than the social value of the emission reductions achieved in Brazil (estimated land-opportunity costs of −US$20.7 billion). Land-opportunity costs are higher in Indonesia than in Brazil, but still lower than the social value of the emissions reduced there (Table 2).

Discussion

Our study presents a new counterfactual land-use allocation model driven by assumptions of satisficing behaviour, heterogeneous farmer expectations and stochastic uncertainty, which can simulate market-oriented decision-making. It provides a suitable business-as-usual baseline to assess the social value of reducing forest losses, where forest conservation generates social value by avoiding emissions. We argue that modelling market-driven forest losses and separating them from non-market-driven losses provides a way to understand the net effect of broad policy interventions and other non-market factors that simultaneously influence forest cover. This approach complements quasi-experimental statistical approaches, which are agnostic to the factors determining the baseline scenario. Additionally, our counterfactuals enable the application of a cutting-edge method4 for quantifying the social (economic) value of changes to emissions from forest losses.

The counterfactual model reflects how landowners will likely respond to changing market forces, capturing very different conditions and deforestation rates ranging from an average of 0.50% (DR Congo, with cassava as the most profitable crop) to 0.58% (Brazil, with soybeans as the most profitable crop) to 1.61% per year (Indonesia, with palm oil as the most profitable crop). Thus, we expect that our approach can be extended to support studies in countries beyond the three considered here.

The assumption of satisficing behaviour supports realistic model outcomes: alternative assumptions would yield different counterfactual predictions. For example, giving more weight to maximizing decision rules would increase simulated reference levels of forest loss to higher than observed forest losses35, whereas our model is able to capture empirically observed variations in forest cover losses across time with relatively little (and exclusively publicly available) input data. Further research could extend our model to include other drivers beyond heterogeneous expected future market prices and agricultural productivities. Finally, it is important to stress that our approach does not provide causal impact estimates and exact figures for specific forest loss reduction policies, instead providing net deviations from a market-only reference scenario. In other studies, highly advanced integrated assessment models are used in prospective studies36 or sophisticated quasi-experimental models for ex-post analyses37. Instead, we present a counterfactual modelling and broad assessment approach as a parsimonious and less data-demanding complement to these techniques while still providing generalizable patterns of likely country-scale drivers of forest losses and a robust estimation of the order of magnitude of the social value of avoided forest losses.

In Brazil, the counterfactual forest cover trajectory identified reduced forest losses at a plausible order of magnitude for 2004–2009, a period that corresponds to the implementation of the ‘Action Plan for the Prevention and Control of Deforestation in the Legal Amazon’ (PPCDAm). For example, ref. 38 found a deforestation reduction of 73,000 km2 (emission reduction of 2.7 gigatonnes CO2), which is similar to our estimated forest loss reduction for the same period (67,000 km2, emission reduction of 3.1 gigatonnes CO2).

Developments in DR Congo from 2012 onwards illustrate how disruptions in social cohesion and local governance structures (here represented by armed conflicts18) can trigger deviations from the expected market-only forest loss trajectory. Displaced populations and forced migrations indicate serious disturbances to local communities and governance, probably eroding land users’ confidence about their ability to exploit future benefits of avoided deforestation. Moving forward, the disturbance of social systems by global or national crises could become an even more important driver of forest loss.

Indonesia is a country characterized by high land-opportunity costs, which are the enemy of any forest conservation39. Trends in forest losses show a climate cooling effect (smaller than in Brazil) from forest loss reductions in 2000–2005, with some social value even after accounting for possible non-permanence of the reduction effect. Our retrospective analysis identifies pre-election promises as important drivers of excess forest losses17, with peaks in 2015–2016 associated with elevated wildfire frequency40. We suggest that several factors may have been underlying the excess deforestation in Indonesia from 2010 onwards. For example, spillover effects were associated with the Indonesian palm oil moratorium leading to increased deforestation41. Additionally, this period was influenced by the REDD+ agreement and a moratorium concerning peatland and primary forests between Indonesia and Norway. While the moratorium was assessed as being cost-effective42, it has probably contributed only marginally to aggregate reductions of CO2 emissions over the period 2011–2018. It will be important to analyse and assess future forest loss trends, for example, regarding the new ‘Omnibus law’ in Indonesia issued in 2020 to support more work opportunities and attract foreign and domestic investments by relaxing regulatory requirements for businesses43.

Our approach accounts for the non-permanence of the cumulative emission reductions achieved by changing forest loss trends. It avoids overestimating the value of forest protection initiatives and offers a transparent and credible means of estimating the social value associated with avoiding forest loss4. Similarly, while past scholarship has been criticized for overstating reference trajectories9, our counterfactual approach provides reference estimates that are independent from (often very high) historical forest losses. Overstating the value of nature-based solutions risks discrediting this crucial set of climate mitigation and adaptation strategies44, which often effectively bundle social and ecological co-benefits.

Here we calculate a social value of past trends of forest losses worth US$61.6 billion even when accounting for the non-permanence of achieved emission reductions. This value climbs to US$92.2 billion if conflict-linked deforestation spikes in DR Congo are ignored. The social value of these avoided emissions alone outweighs the forgone private agricultural net benefits imposed by forest conservation, and carbon storage is just one part of the total social value provided by tropical forest3. For Brazil, we calculate that the social value of avoided emissions (US$72.2 billion) is 3.5 times the private agricultural land-opportunity costs. This result supports the findings of a recent global study45 that found benefit–cost ratios of general global climate policies ranging between 1.5 and 3.9. Our result is even more remarkable, as we used SCC to assess past trends of forest losses at the lower end of recently published SCC46.

The economic valuation of the benefits and costs associated with the services of nature comes with criticism47. However, our study highlights that reducing forest losses, even when faced with the risk of non-permanence31, may generate real economic benefits, which humans cannot afford to ignore. Provided that credible methods to assess their potential are used, one can value how such solutions may effectively complement efforts to reduce human greenhouse gas emissions elsewhere31. We argue that valuing avoided emissions from forest losses is important because the magnitude of their social value vastly outweighs imperfections in assessment methods. Doing so may help to identify leverage points for sustainable development, for example reducing perverse incentive structures that redirect capital to projects that generate net social and environmental harm48,49.

Among the limitations of our counterfactuals is a lack of spatial detail in modelled forest losses; no local inference is possible with this first version of our model. Other limitations include the problem that several influences may overlap. For example, another study has shown that mining has been responsible for 9% of the forest losses in the Brazilian Amazon from 2005–201514. However, possible mining-related excess forest losses were probably compensated by simultaneous command-and-control policies at the country scale. We limited the factors included in our counterfactual model to market price signals, productivities and the associated profit expectations of farmers, but other factors can also be influential (for example, the effects of changing discount rates50 or movements of exchange rates51). We suggest that such effects have partially been encapsulated by market price signals52. Additionally, non-monetary factors, such as access to labour53, as well as cultural values54 can influence the level of forest loss. Our counterfactual model can be advanced to integrate such factors by including multiple objectives to be satisfied35.

We conclude that generating suitable reference scenarios is pivotal for analysing forest loss trends, as one cannot intersubjectively assess what one cannot measure21. Our approach enables the identification not only of trends but also of possible drivers. Illustrating trends and estimating their social value can be an important communication strategy. Our estimates of the social value of inducing changes to expected forest loss rates are moderate but encouraging, particularly for Brazil’s case, providing a proof-of-concept that past deforestation reductions were of substantial social value, even if they were short-lived. This underlines both the feasibility and the urgency of integrating the economic dimensions of forest losses into decision-making55 and welfare-accounting systems56 to harness the momentum of the Glasgow Leaders’ Declaration on Forests and Land Use.

Achieving larger and more enduring reductions in forest losses is among society’s greatest challenges. Here we show that efforts to protect forests can also be economically rewarding. Future initiatives could address the causes rather than the symptoms57 of forest loss, including the demand side for agricultural commodities13, and influence the social identity58 of land managers rather than considering their actual behaviour as a mistake to be corrected.

Methods

Counterfactual deforestation model

The common maximization paradigm in land-use models implies that land managers would always seek, for example, the maximum productivity, service provisioning, net present value, utility or profit. Such analyses commonly assume just one future condition or average alternative scenario outcomes (sometimes using probabilities as weights). However, the uncertain real world does not allow application of the maximization assumption for many land managers because the one land-use allocation that achieves a maximum outcome across all possible future scenarios would not be available. Moreover, maximizing the average of all possible scenarios might be acceptable for rich land managers but not for those needing acceptable land-use income each year. We thus started with the premise that satisficing behaviour is a more reasonable and consistent assumption for land-use decisions28, given that multiple futures are possible and that decision-makers have imperfect information on the likelihood of occurrence of these futures. Uncertainty includes market price and productivity fluctuations, as well as potential crop losses by natural hazards and sudden political changes. Land managers consider multiple possible profits for the future in our model. In our approach, satisficing means that land managers gradually improve their current land-use profits by seeking a compromise land-use allocation that promises ‘sufficient’ outcome levels for all states of the world they assume are possible. To achieve this, individual land managers would consider two types of information: (1) profits they expect under current land-use allocation and (2) the best achievable profits they expect under a changed land allocation (for multiple possible future profit scenarios). Our suggested model (see Fig. 1 for workflow) captures the potential for improvement by the difference between (2) and (1), which shows the degree of land manager dissatisfaction with current profits. Groups of farmers then reallocated land between land-use/land-cover (LULC) types, seeking to reduce the maximum difference between (2) and (1) across multiple (randomly simulated) future profits they expect. However, in contrast to a previous model35, we used a large range of stochastic profit scenarios to acknowledge that individual expectations are heterogeneous59. This implies that not all farmers would contribute equally to LULC changes, but mainly those who see the largest potential for improving their profits (that is, those who experience the largest dissatisfaction with current profits). While we clustered individual land managers into groups (to represent potential regional heterogeneity), we assumed that such groups would arrange their land-use allocation in a way that minimizes their maximum dissatisfaction across multiple future profit expectations over time, taking their heterogeneous profit expectations into account. The simulated market-driven counterfactual forest loss predicts the expected annual reduction of the area cover of the LULC type ‘natural forest’ (Supplementary Methods 1, equation (1)). For a mathematical description of our counterfactual deforestation model, see Supplementary Methods 1.

Observed forest losses

Observed forest losses were taken from Global Forest Watch60, defined as ‘… the complete removal of tree cover canopy at the Landsat pixel scale’. Data from FAO Statistics61 refer to annual area reductions of the LULC class ‘naturally regenerating forest’ (Supplementary Methods 1). Forest losses included both deforestation (permanent loss of forest) and temporary forest losses (for example, due to natural forest fires) partly followed by forest regrowth. We excluded extensive forest losses due to natural fires in Brazil and Indonesia (2016 and 2017), which are probably temporary, from the assessment of the social value of the forest loss trends. Solid remote sensing data underlie Global Forest Watch forest losses, which rely on a method developed in ref. 62. We compared observed and counterfactual forest losses to identify deviations from reference trajectories of forest losses, these deviations being manifested as periods of reduction or excess of deforestation. The FAO-reported data show that Brazil, DR Congo and Indonesia account for 43% of the average global net forest losses over the period 2009–2019 (Supplementary Fig. 3, based on ref. 61).

Model assessment

The influence of the reduction and excess periods of forest losses affected by non-market factors on the level of forest loss (Lobs) was statistically analysed using a generalized linear mixed model to evaluate the quality of the counterfactual model. Countries were defined as subjects and the year of the observation as the repeated measure variable. We evaluated the portion of the variation of the observed forest losses (Lobs) that can be explained by the estimates \(\hat{{L}^{{\mathrm{obs}}}}\), using the counterfactual forest losses Lref, and the reduction and excess phases as predictors (Supplementary Fig. 2).

$$\begin{array}{rcl}\hat{{L}^{{\mathrm{obs}}}} &=& a+b\times {R}^{{\mathrm{Bra}}1}+c\times {R}^{{\mathrm{Bra}}2}+d\times {R}^{{\mathrm{Ind}}}+e\times {{\mathrm{EX}}}^{{\mathrm{Bra}}}\\&&+f\times {{\mathrm{EX}}}^{{\mathrm{Con}}}+g \times {{\mathrm{EX}}}^{{\mathrm{Ind}}}+h \times {L}^{{\mathrm{ref}}}\end{array}$$
(1)

Bra1 is Brazil reduction period 1, Bra2 is Brazil reduction period 2, Ind is Indonesia, Bra is Brazil, Con is DR Congo and ref is counterfactual forest loss. Reduction (R) and excess periods (EX) were contrasted against a reference level of 0 (≈phase of market-oriented forest loss).

Equation (1) considers market-oriented counterfactual forest losses by variable Lref, but also controls for the impact of periods influenced by non-market factors. One would expect that, given unbiased counterfactual (reference) forest losses, the coefficient h of the variable Lref would obtain a value close to one. In fact, we obtained h = +0.969 (see Supplementary Table 1).

Country-level influences on the level of forest loss

We used ref. 63, which structured the drivers of forest loss into proximate causes and underlying driving forces, as an orientation to identify potential country-scale factors driving forest loss. The underlying forces mentioned in ref. 63 included economic factors (which our counterfactuals covered using production values computed as prices × productivities), institutional and policy influences, remote factors, but also behavioural factors (which our counterfactuals considered by assuming satisficing decision-making). Examples of the proximate causes included agricultural expansion, wood extraction and infrastructure extension. Social events (such as revolution) and biophysical drivers (for example, climate events) were classified as between the underlying and proximate levels.

While our counterfactual model included already important underlying drivers (agricultural productivities, market prices and consistent satisficing decision behaviour), we also searched for country-scale factors as possible causes for deviations of observed from counterfactual forest losses. These factors represented institutional and policy factors (for example, command-and-control policies and pre-election promises), social events (for example, conflicts) and extreme climate events (for example, biophysical drivers). On the basis of literature searches, we qualitatively tested whether such factors, for which reliable evidence had been published, temporarily coincided with deviations from the counterfactuals. Concerning factors supporting a reduction in forest losses, these selection criteria were met for command-and-control policies associated with the PPCDAm, launched in 2004 by Brazil’s government. These policies included land planning, establishing and expanding protected areas, remote sensing-based monitoring and control, environmental licences, fines for illegal deforestation and on-the-ground enforcement of the law15. Domestic political interventions to reduce forest losses, such as agreements with meat companies and a soy moratorium, were also established51. The moratorium banned trading, financing or purchasing of soybeans produced on land parcels previously covered by rainforest. As an approximate end of the period under command-and-control policies, the Brazilian Forest Code was established in 201215, which weakened the initially ambitious deforestation reduction aims. In the case of Indonesia, command-and-control policies were associated with Forestry Act No. 41 in 1999 (which we considered for 2000–2005 following ref. 64), according to which everybody had to protect the environment and forests65. This legal act also supported more stringent forest clearing permission rules enforced by the government and consistently applied fiscal measures, such as export taxes (limiting the attractiveness of exporting palm oil), implemented after a change in the government64. On factors potentially leading to excess forest losses, we suggest social disturbances by armed conflicts in DR Congo as a possible cause of higher-than-expected deforestation from 2012 onwards. A strong increase in conflicts has been documented from 2009 onwards in DR Congo (from below 1,000 to almost 3,500 cases per year)18. Main conflict types were battles, violence against civilians and riots or protests. For Indonesia, we suggest perverse political incentives (pre-election promotion of agricultural development and additional harvesting concessions) as regional-level factors driving excess forest losses from 2010 onwards. The number of direct elections was shown to be significantly positively correlated with the level of forest loss17. Finally, we traced back extreme peaks of forest losses (mainly in Brazil, but also in Indonesia) to the extreme climate events of 2016. Local and other factors potentially influencing the level of forest loss but not included in our approach are discussed in Supplementary Methods 3.

Social value and opportunity costs

Our counterfactual forest loss trajectories facilitated quantifying the social value of avoiding CO2 emissions, here based on our real-world example of reducing forest losses. Our assessment method was guided by a newly developed method4 to value nature-based emission reductions starting with the social costs of carbon (SCCt), which aggregate the costs of damages caused by one additional unit of CO2 emitted today from a societal perspective over an unlimited period.

$${{\mathrm{SCC}}}_{t}=\mathop{\sum }\limits_{t}^{{\rm{\infty }}}{\left(1+r\right)}^{-t} \times {D}_{t}$$
(2)

Dt is the temperature-dependent marginal damage (in US$) caused by the emission of one unit CO2 emitted in one specific year, which increases at a constant rate per year in our study, and r is the constant discount rate (r = 0.03 in our case33). SCCt data were taken from ref. 33 and Dt grew at 0.0202 per annum (derived from data in ref. 34).

The basic equation derived in ref. 4 to assess the social value V of avoided CO2 emissions under the premise of permanence of the emission reduction and climate effects after T (T is when our consideration ends) is as follows:

$$V=\mathop{\sum }\limits_{t=0}^{T=19}{\left(1+r\right)}^{-t} \times {E}_{t} \times \mathrm{{SC}{C}}_{t}=\mathop{\sum }\limits_{t=0}^{{\rm{\infty }}}{\left(1+r\right)}^{-t}{ \times S}_{t}\times {D}_{t}$$
(3)

Et is either an annual reduction of CO2 emissions relative to the counterfactual, contributing positively to the social value of the trend of forest loss, or an increase, contributing negatively to the social value (Supplementary Methods 4.1). St is the stock of the accumulated avoided (positive St) or additional emissions (negative St), which we assumed to become constant from T onwards.

$${S}_{t}=\mathop{\sum }\limits_{0}^{t}{E}_{t}$$
(4)

To account for the possibility of a reversion of the carbon stocks to their initial values (=non-permanence), we assumed a likelihood of reversion of 1% per annum from T onwards. This assumption was implemented by using an adjusted social value V* to account for possible non-permanence. V* uses the year 2019 as reference year for the present value.

$${V}^{* }=\mathop{\sum }\limits_{t=0}^{T=19}{\left(1+r\right)}^{19-t}{ \times S}_{t}{ \times D}_{t}+\mathop{\sum }\limits_{t=20}^{{\rm{\infty }}}{\left(1+r\right)}^{-\left(t-19\right)}{ \times {\left(1+\rho \right)}^{-\left(t-19\right)} \times S}_{t}{ \times D}_{t}$$
(5)

ρ is the probability of reversion to the pre-assessment state per annum (ρ = 0.01 in our case). For the SCCt and Dt, see Supplementary Table 9 and Supplementary Methods 4.2.

Our estimation of the land-opportunity costs (economic net benefits land managers forgo when refraining from forest clearing) caused by tropical forest conservation followed the same logic as our estimation of the social value of emission reductions. The land-opportunity costs represent the foregone net benefits for land managers when they decide to retain tropical forest instead of converting them to alternative LULC types. These costs were calculated by considering the expected relative contributions of different LULC types to the simulated forest losses (Supplementary Table 10). Due to changing market prices and productivities, we obtained specific opportunity costs for each period. The aggregated costs result from:

$$C=\mathop{\sum }\limits_{t=0}^{{\rm{\infty }}}{\left(1+r\right)}^{-t} \times {S}_{t}^{\Delta L}\times {O}_{t}$$
(6)

\({S}_{t}^{\Delta L}\) is the accumulated area of the avoided forest losses (enhancing \({S}_{t}^{\Delta L}\)) or of the additional forest losses (reducing \({S}_{t}^{\Delta L}\)), which we assumed to become constant from T onwards. Ot is the land-opportunity cost per hectare per year, growing at 0.007 per annum in Brazil and at 0.004 per annum in Indonesia after T (Supplementary Table 10).

$${S}_{t}^{\Delta L}=\mathop{\sum }\limits_{0}^{t}{\Delta L}_{t}$$
(7)

Lt is the difference between observed and expected area of forest losses. To account for the possibility of a reversion, we also assumed a likelihood of reversion of 1% per annum here, from T onwards.

$$\begin{array}{rcl}{C}^{* }& =& \mathop{\sum }\limits_{t=0}^{T=19}{\left(1+r\right)}^{19-t} \times {S}_{t}^{\Delta L}\times {O}_{t}\\ && +\mathop{\sum }\limits_{t=20}^{{\rm{\infty }}}{\left(1+r\right)}^{-\left(t-19\right)}{\times \left(1+\rho \right)}^{-\left(t-19\right)}\times {S}_{t}^{\Delta L}\times {O}_{t}\end{array}$$
(8)

C* are the land-opportunities accounting for non-permanence. As the discount rate to estimate opportunity costs, we used the same r = 0.03 used for assessing climate benefits.

Reporting summary

Further information on research design is available in the Nature Portfolio Reporting Summary linked to this article.