Main

Authority, a form of social power vested in a culturally recognized role or office and exercised over a specific group of people1, is one of the defining characteristics of complex, large-scale societies. In small groups where a large proportion of members can interact directly, group decisions can be made on an informal and non-authoritarian basis. However, groups of more than a few thousand people generally require systems of command and control to make and implement group decisions2,3. During the Holocene, the scale and complexity of human societies increased immensely, and systems of authority became correspondingly more complex and ubiquitous2,4.

A few small-scale societies reportedly lack authority altogether5. However, most societies (including those otherwise considered egalitarian) recognize authority at some level, minimally that of a household head over other household members4,5. In hierarchical societies, authority may be exercised over a sublocal group such as a clan or village ward, a local community such as a village or district, or a supralocal grouping such as a chiefdom or state, with higher levels of authority usually subsuming rather than replacing lower levels2,3. In addition to varying in its scope, authority varies in the domains of social life to which it applies. Many ethnographers distinguish between political (also ‘secular’, ‘temporal’ or ‘civil’) authority and religious (‘ritual’, ‘sacred’, ‘spiritual’ and so on) authority6,7,8. For some ethnographers, this distinction turns on the means by which authority operates, with political authority based on physical force and religious authority relying on supernatural sanctions or supernatural legitimacy7,8. Others make this distinction in terms of the ends to which authority is directed. Firth6 describes politics as “focused on relations of men with other men”, in contrast to religion, which “is more oriented to relations of men with gods or other spiritually conceived forces”, and Garland9 defines religious authority as “the right…to act authoritatively both in the name of and in matters of, religion”. Here we use the ends-based distinction. We operationalize religious authority as a right to manage interactions between living human beings and supernatural agents or powers and political authority as a right to manage interactions between living human beings.

Scholars acknowledge the historical interdependence of religion and politics, and by extension religious and political authority6, but often emphasize one over the other. In many theories of political evolution, religion is downplayed, being either ignored altogether10 or seen as merely underpinning or legitimizing existing political arrangements1,11. In others, religion is seen as foundational to politics, and religious authority is seen as the earliest form of authority12,13,14. Still others acknowledge a reciprocal relationship between religion and politics without assigning precedence to either. Religious expertise may be seen as one of multiple paths to power15, or prosocial religious beliefs may be seen as having predisposed certain groups to evolve into large, complex societies16. A variant of this position is that religion and politics are so closely interwoven in most pre-modern societies that they cannot be meaningfully separated17.

When religious and political authority are found in the same society, they can be differentiated to a greater or lesser degree. In many societies, they are combined in the same office (as in a polity headed by a priest-king or priest-chief), but in others religious and political power are wielded by distinct leaders who may cooperate or compete6,18. Many scholars have argued that the earliest forms of religious and political authority were combined, making distinct religious and political hierarchies a later development14,19. The opposing view that the earliest forms of religious and political authority were distinct is also encountered occasionally. The divine kingship of Hawaii, for example, has been explained as the outcome of a process whereby political leaders gained progressively more religious authority20, presumably at the expense of more specialized religious figures. How religious and political authority have coevolved and whether there are historical regularities in their pattern of differentiation and fusion are separate but related questions, since one of the most obvious ways for religious and political authority to coevolve would be for both forms of authority to be vested in the same office.

Archaeological and historical evidence suggests answers to both questions. Archaeologists note that in most early city-states, the earliest monumental structures appear to have served religious rather than secular purposes14,21,22, suggesting that religious authority may have come first. The extent to which the earliest forms of authority were differentiated is more difficult to infer from the archaeological record. However, the earliest written records clearly indicate that in at least one area of primary state formation, Mesopotamia, religious and political authority were initially combined and later became partly distinct21. Presently, the incompleteness of the historical and archaeological records leaves these questions unresolved.

Cultural phylogenetic methods can complement the archaeological record by using ethnographic data to infer the evolutionary histories of cultural traits—a technique called “virtual archaeology”23. These methods typically rely on language trees or phylogenies to model cultural ancestry24. Since there is no widely recognized phylogeny of the world’s languages, cultural phylogenetic studies usually focus on cultural variation within a single recognized language family. The Austronesian language family of Southeast Asia and the Pacific has proved particularly well suited to a cultural phylogenetic approach. It is the second-largest language family whose taxonomic status is uncontroversial25, and the societies that speak Austronesian languages are remarkably diverse. As well as having a great variety of social and political structures26, the Austronesian-speaking world was until recently home to a large number of indigenous religions that were similarly diverse and are relatively well documented27. Because of these advantages, there have already been a number of cultural phylogenetic studies of Austronesian-speaking societies28,29,30, including at least two that have examined the coevolution of socio-political phenomena and elements of religious belief and practice31,32.

Here we present a cultural phylogenetic study of the evolution of religious and political authority in the Austronesian-speaking world. On the basis of ethnographic descriptions, we coded 97 Austronesian-speaking societies with respect to whether they had systems of religious and/or political authority and, if applicable, the scale of the social groups that these systems encompassed. In societies in which both religious and political authority were present, we also coded the extent to which the two were differentiated. These variables were coded on four-point ordinal scales (Methods). We mapped the traits onto trees representing relationships between the languages spoken in these societies and reconstructed their evolutionary histories under different model assumptions to infer causal dependencies and patterns of differentiation.

Results

Coevolution

Our first series of phylogenetic analyses focused on the coevolution of religious and political authority. We coded both religious and political authority as ordinal variables with four possible states: absent (not present above the household level), sublocal (incorporating a group larger than the household but smaller than the local community), local (incorporating the local community) and supralocal (incorporating more than one local community). Both of these variables showed high phylogenetic signal (ƛ) (political authority: ƛ = 0.58; 95% highest posterior density interval (HPDI), (0.00, 0.80); religious authority: ƛ = 0.55; 95% HPDI, (0.00, 0.78); Extended Data Fig. 1) and were positively phylogenetically correlated (phylogenetic correlation, 0.78; 95% HPDI, (0.25, 0.99); residual correlation, 0.20; 95% HPDI, (−0.56, 0.94); Extended Data Fig. 2), suggesting that their evolution could reasonably be modelled as a dynamic coevolutionary process. Previous approaches to testing for the coevolution of cultural traits have only allowed the use of binary variables30,31,32, resulting in a loss of information and hence statistical power. Here we overcome this limitation by assuming that each of the ordinal variables represents a latent continuous trait and modelling their coevolution using a recently developed Bayesian phylogenetic method that allows inferences to be made about the influence of two or more traits of any distribution on each other, as well as the role of ‘selection’ and ‘drift’ in the evolution of each33. Since linguistic distances between societies were positively correlated with geographic distances (r = 0.31; 95% confidence interval, (0.28 0.33); d.f. = 4,654; P < 0.001; Extended Data Fig. 3), we adjusted for geographic distance in our model to mitigate any confounding effects of cultural diffusion or similar environments. Analysis of simulated data indicated that this model was able to accurately recover true parameter values (Extended Data Fig. 4), and standard post-analysis checks suggested that the model converged normally (Extended Data Fig. 5).

We found evidence for a reciprocal coevolutionary relationship between religious and political authority. Figure 1 presents the posterior change in the equilibrium trait value of one trait resulting from an absolute deviation increase in the other trait, and vice versa. Given the model, the data and our priors, we can be 97% certain that an absolute deviation increase in political authority results in an increase in religious authority at equilibrium (median posterior value, 2.44; 95% HPDI, (−0.03, 4.87); log Bayes factor (BF), 4.62). Similarly, we can be 94% certain that an absolute deviation increase in religious authority results in an increase in political authority at equilibrium (median posterior value, 2.00; 95% HPDI, (−0.53, 4.65); log BF, 2.84). We found no evidence of a difference between these two distributions (median posterior difference, −0.54; 95% HPDI, (−4.14, 3.63); log BF, −0.50) and hence no clear evidence that either form of authority had precedence.

Fig. 1: Posterior distribution showing probability densities of changes in the equilibrium trait value θ of political authority (Pol) and religious authority (Rel) in response to a standardized unit increase in the other trait.
figure 1

Posterior probabilities (PPs) denote the positive posterior mass (that is, the probability), given the model and the data, that an increase in political authority leads to an increase in religious authority, and vice versa. The values were scaled by the median absolute deviation, which is less sensitive to outliers than the standard deviation. The grey inset represents the posterior difference between the two distributions.

Further inspection of the model dynamics revealed that combinations involving high levels of one trait and low levels of the other were unstable (Fig. 2 and Extended Data Fig. 6). When religious authority was low and political authority was high, there was strong positive selection on religious authority and negative selection on political authority. Similarly, when political authority was low and religious authority was high, there was strong positive selection on political authority and negative selection on religious authority. These model dynamics entail runaway selection for each type of authority, such that authority levels enter a positive feedback loop and do not return to any stable equilibrium.

Fig. 2: Phase plane showing the expected change in levels of political and religious authority depending on the state of the other trait.
figure 2

The authority variables are on the latent scale. The dashed lines are posterior median ordinal cutpoints, and the spaces between these represent the expected authority levels: absent, sublocal, local and supralocal. The grey arrows indicate the direction (orientation) and strength (size) of selection.

The coevolutionary model also illuminates the evolution of political and religious authority over time, providing estimated probabilities of different authority levels for ancestral nodes in the Austronesian language phylogeny (Fig. 3 and Extended Data Fig. 7). On the basis of our analysis, local political and religious authority is the most likely state for Proto-Austronesian society. In the more recent Proto-Central Pacific node, the probability of supralocal religious and political authority increases, and it becomes the most likely state in Proto-Polynesian. These reconstructions are consistent with previous work that has reconstructed the evolutionary history of political complexity in the Austronesian world28 and the socio-religious system of Proto-Polynesian society specifically34.

Fig. 3: Observed data and ancestral state reconstructions mapped onto a maximum clade credibility tree for the Austronesian language phylogeny.
figure 3

The colours at the tips represent the observed levels of religious authority (left) and political authority (right) across 97 Austronesian societies. The shading of the branches represents the median posterior values of the continuous latent variables at each ancestral node, implied by the coevolutionary model. Darker shading indicates higher levels of authority in ancestral state reconstructions. The pie charts show the median posterior probabilities of each authority level for the following ancestral nodes: Proto-Austronesian (a), Proto-Malayo-Polynesian (b), Proto-Oceanic (c), Proto-Central-Pacific (d) and Proto-Polynesian (e). These five nodes were selected on the basis of previous work (see, for example, ref. 35).

Sequential evolution

In our second series of phylogenetic analyses, we tested for patterns of differentiation and fusion in systems of religious and political authority. We coded the structure of religious and political authority as one of four possible states: none (one or both forms of authority lacking above the household level), combined (vested in the same office or offices), partly independent (for example, vested in distinct offices that are part of the same hierarchy) and independent (vested in distinct offices that are not part of the same hierarchy). We tested four sequential models of trait evolution against a full model that allowed any transition between any level of differentiation (Fig. 4). Two of the sequential models required more differentiated authority structures to evolve from less differentiated ones. These differentiation models consisted of a strong version and a weak version. In the strong version, independent could evolve only from partly independent, and partly independent could evolve only from combined, whereas the weak version also allowed a direct transition from combined to independent. The other two sequential models required less differentiated authority structures to evolve from more differentiated ones. These unification models also consisted of a strong version (which required combined to evolve from partly independent, and partly independent to evolve from independent) and a weak version (which also allowed a direct transition from independent to combined). We evaluated the various models by comparing log BFs calculated from the log marginal likelihoods estimated by the analyses. The results were equivocal: no model outperformed any of the others (Supplementary Table 1).

Fig. 4: Five models of the evolution of religious and political authority.
figure 4

a, In the full model, any transition between any two states is allowed. b, In the weak differentiation model, independent systems of authority must evolve from either combined or partly independent systems, and partly independent systems must evolve from combined systems. c, In the strong differentiation model, independent systems of authority must evolve from partly independent systems of authority, which in turn must evolve from combined systems of authority. d, In the weak unification model, combined systems of authority must evolve from either independent or partly independent systems of authority, and partly independent systems of authority must evolve from independent systems of authority. e, In the strong unification model, combined systems of authority must evolve from partly independent systems of authority, which in turn must evolve from independent systems of authority.

Discussion

We found evidence for a reciprocal coevolutionary dependency between religious and political authority in our sample. The relationship could have been direct or could have been the result of a third variable, which may have corresponded to a higher-level concept encompassing both religious and political authority. Regardless, we found no evidence that either form of authority had causal precedence. Furthermore, we did not find any evidence for long-term patterns of differentiation or fusion in systems of religious and political authority.

A direct coevolutionary relationship between religious and political authority seems highly plausible given ethnographic descriptions of the two institutions being closely intertwined. In many Austronesian societies, supreme religious and political authority were vested in the same office, the divine kingship of Hawaii being perhaps the best-known example35. In others there was a partial separation of religious and political authority. The details varied. The two institutions might be vested in different offices that were part of the same hierarchy. In Tonga, the priestly Tu’i Tonga outranked more powerful political rulers36, whereas in Roviana, ‘chiefs’ (bangara) enjoyed supremacy over ‘high priests’ (ngati hiama) except in religious matters37. Other arrangements were less straightforward. Tikopia was ruled by four chiefs (ariki) who had equal political status, but one of these chiefs (the Ariki Kafika) was “in island-wide religious ceremonies…clearly pre-eminent”38. Even in societies where religious and political leaders enjoyed de jure independence and were sometimes opposed, they usually headed the same social group and often worked together closely. In Tahiti, for example, high priests are reported to have “exercised immense influence” in secular affairs, “depending more or less on the character of the king”39. The ethnographic sources often explicitly describe religious authority as supporting political authority by legitimizing it and reinforcing it with supernatural sanctions. In Chuuk, for example, the itang (‘political priests’) “legitimized chiefship through divine sanction and the spirit power (manaman) that went with it”, according to one source40. Given the centrality of religious belief and practice in pre-modern societies13, it seems likely that aspiring political leaders who lacked either religious authority of their own or the support of religious leaders would have struggled to gain and maintain power. It is less obvious why religious authority would have depended so heavily on political authority, but political support might have strengthened religious authority by increasing its prestige and resource base and perhaps also by helping suppress challenges to its monopoly.

The interdependence that we observed could also reflect a third variable that simultaneously caused changes in both political and religious authority. Authority itself—that is, a higher-level phenomenon encompassing both religious and political authority—is perhaps the most likely candidate. There are obvious reasons why a society with any given form of authority might have been more likely to gain (and less likely to lose) any other form. New forms of authority could have been vested in existing offices rather than requiring the creation of new ones, and existing forms of authority could have been transferred from defunct offices to remaining offices, increasing the redundancy in the system and reducing the chance of specific forms of authority being lost. Existing forms of authority could also have served as models for new ones, and populations that had already accepted one form of authority might well have been more willing to accept others. Social (or cultural) complexity, an even more encompassing phenomenon that may or may not represent a single underlying construct41,42,43, is another plausible third variable. Environmental variables such as circumscription or resource concentration10 could have played a role, though the fact that we controlled for geographic distance makes this seem less likely.

The interdependence between religious and political authority observed in the present study and its apparent lack of directionality are in keeping with the results of two previous studies that examined the coevolution of religious beliefs and practices with other socio-political traits and found evidence of reciprocal relationships31,32. Nevertheless, while our results do not support a directional relationship, the limitations of our data prevent us from ruling it out entirely. The coding of religious and political authority as ordinal variables with four states is likely to have made religious and political authority correspond somewhat more closely than they did in actuality. For example, the Toba Batak were coded as having both supralocal religious and supralocal political authority. However, although both religious and political authority existed on a supralocal level among the Toba Batak, the scope of religious authority was much greater. Some powerful chiefs governed groups of villages with combined populations of up to a thousand, but tens or perhaps even hundreds of thousands acknowledged the religious authority of the priest-king Si Singamangaraja44. Had a finer-grained coding system been feasible, it is possible that more evidence for directionality would have been observed.

The lack of support for patterns of differentiation or fusion in systems of religious and political authority may partly reflect sample characteristics. The fact that all or almost all early states had combined systems of political and religious authority22 suggests that if there is a sustained trend towards differentiation, this trend emerges only in societies that have already reached the state level. Pre-colonial Austronesian societies varied greatly in their complexity, but there were few state-level societies45 and fewer still among those who retained their indigenous religions until the modern era.

The societies in our sample represent only a fraction of the total number of Austronesian societies, and some areas (for example, Vanuatu) are undersampled relative to others (for example, Polynesia). We cannot be certain that our results generalize to the Austronesian-speaking world as a whole, let alone to the rest of the world. Nevertheless, the diversity of the societies in the sample, which occupy all corners of the Austronesian-speaking world and range from acephalous to state-level, gives us some confidence that the interdependence we observe is a real and general phenomenon. Further research could, of course, test the extent to which our findings apply elsewhere.

The present study found evidence for a reciprocal coevolutionary relationship between religious and political authority in the Austronesian-speaking world. This relationship could have been direct, caused by a third factor or both. We found no clear evidence for or against a progression from less differentiated to more differentiated systems of authority. Our results suggest that theories of cultural evolution that ignore or sideline religion are incomplete. Although many authors have argued that religious and political authority have coevolved, the present study provides quantitative evidence of the closeness of this relationship as well as specific insights into how these two institutions have worked synergistically during the evolution of large-scale societies.

Methods

Phylogenies

We modelled cultural ancestry using a sample of 1,000 trees from the posterior distribution of a previously published Bayesian reconstruction of the Austronesian language family. This set of trees originally included 400 taxa, 363 of which corresponded to unique Austronesian languages29. Of these languages, 109 corresponded to one of the 97 societies in our ethnographic dataset. None corresponded to more than one society. Only eight societies (Atayal, Bontok, Ifugao, Minahasa, Nendö, Tanimbar, Tanna and Visayans) corresponded to more than one language. In these cases, we took the conservative approach of selecting only one language per society, choosing the language with the greatest number of speakers according to Ethnologue46. The pruning of phylogenies employed the packages ape47 and geiger48 in the programming language R49. The pruned set of phylogenies is available via the Open Science Framework (https://osf.io/cm53v/).

Coding of variables

We coded 97 Austronesian-speaking societies with respect to three variables: religious authority, political authority and the structure of religious and political authority. Authority was defined as a form of social power vested in a specific social role or office and exercised over a specific group of people3. Religious authority was defined as a right to manage interactions between living human beings and supernatural agents or powers, whereas political authority was defined as a right to manage interactions between living human beings6,9. The variables ‘religious authority’ and ‘political authority’ each had the same four states. Societies in which the relevant form of authority did not exist or encompassed a group no larger than the household were coded 0 (authority at the household level was ignored partly because of its near-universality and partly because of the difficulty inherent in separating de jure authority from de facto power at the household level). Societies in which the relevant form of authority existed above the household level were coded 1 if the group it incorporated was sublocal (smaller than the local community), 2 if the group was local (coextensive with the local community) or consisted of multiple sublocal groups, and 3 if the group was supralocal (consisting of more than one local community). The local community was defined as “the maximal group of persons who normally reside together in face-to-face association”50.

The variable ‘structure of religious and political authority’ represented the extent to which religious and political authority were differentiated. Societies were coded 0 if religious or political authority or both were lacking above the household level. If supreme religious and political authority were combined (vested in the same office or offices), the society was coded 1. Societies in which supreme religious and political authority were partly independent were coded 2. This was something of a residual category that included societies in which the two forms of authority were incompletely partitioned between different offices (for example, supreme political authority being vested in one office and supreme religious authority shared between this office and another) as well as those in which they were vested in different offices that were part of the same hierarchy (for example, a high priest being the subject of a secular high chief, or vice versa). Finally, societies in which supreme religious and political authority were independent (vested in different offices that were not part of the same hierarchy) were coded 3.

Austronesian societies have undergone dramatic changes in their religious and political organization through contact with non-Austronesian societies, particularly over the past few centuries. Almost all Austronesian societies underwent some form of colonization that resulted in permanent changes to their political systems. Moreover, almost all Austronesian speakers now affiliate with either Christianity or Islam, which have either replaced or supplemented their traditional religious beliefs and practices51. The cultural phylogenetic methods used in the present study assume predominantly vertical (within-lineage) cultural transmission52, and so applying them to ethnographic data from Austronesian societies today is unlikely to be informative and could well be misleading. Hence, societies were coded as they were immediately prior to colonization and/or large-scale conversion to a world religion (whichever occurred earlier). Coding was based on a range of ethnographic sources. The data, along with citations and detailed notes justifying each coding decision, are provided in the most recent version of Pulotu27, a database of Austronesian religions.

Assessing phylogenetic signal and correlation

We assessed the strength of phylogenetic signal for political and religious authority (that is, the proportion of variance captured by phylogeny53), as well as the phylogenetic correlation between these variables, using a Bayesian phylogenetic generalized linear mixed model (see the Supplementary Methods for the full model formula). For this model, we used generic, weakly regularizing priors to impose conservatism on parameter estimates and facilitate model convergence. We iterated the model over 100 randomly drawn posterior trees. The model was fitted in R v.4.0.2 (ref. 49) with the brms package54 running Stan55. Standard Markov chain Monte Carlo (MCMC) diagnostics (Ȓ ≤ 1.05) and trace plots suggested that the model converged normally.

Dynamic coevolutionary model

While our phylogenetic generalized linear mixed model indicated a phylogenetic correlation between political and religious authority, this static model could not distinguish directionality or contingencies in coevolution. To give us more insight into how these two variables have coevolved, we used a dynamic model of cultural change over the phylogenetic tree. Many authors have implemented this approach using the Discrete component of the software package BayesTraits56, but that method is limited to binary traits. To avoid having to dichotomize our ordinal variables, we used a recently developed Bayesian method for dynamic coevolutionary analyses that can accommodate any number of traits of any distribution33. With this approach, ordinal traits are modelled as latent continuous variables evolving under selection (both autoregressive selection and cross-trait selection) and drift, similar to a multivariate Ornstein–Uhlenbeck model. The estimation of continuous latent authority levels in the model does not necessarily assume sequential evolution from one authority state to the next, since more than one observed authority state can be consistent with the same latent authority level. The parameters representing selection are used to derive standardized, directed measures of the strength of coevolution between variables (Δθz, as shown in Fig. 1).

As in our assessment of phylogenetic signal, we used generic, weakly regularizing priors. We iterated the model over 100 randomly drawn posterior trees. We additionally included a Gaussian process with longitude and latitude values for each society to control for spatial proximity. The model was fitted in R v.4.0.2b48 with the rstan package running Stan54. Standard MCMC diagnostics (Ȓ ≤ 1.01) and trace plots suggested that the model converged normally (Extended Data Fig. 5). Log BFs were computed for individual parameters by doubling the natural logarithm of the BF, computed with the bayestestR package57.

Simulations of the dynamic coevolutionary model

We ran simulations to confirm that our coevolutionary model could capture the true parameter values. We fixed several parameters in the model (specifically, parameters reflecting the strength of selection and drift) and generated 100 simulated datasets. Next, we fitted the coevolutionary model to each of these datasets and determined whether the 95% credible intervals for the posterior distributions contained the true parameter values. The results of the simulations showed that the coevolutionary model adequately recovered true parameter values (Extended Data Fig. 4).

Sequential evolution

Models of sequential evolution were tested using the Multistate component of the software package BayesTraits (v.3.0)56. Multistate tests model the evolution of a single trait that adopts two or more discrete states, and they can be run using either a maximum likelihood or MCMC approach. The analyses reported in the present study used an MCMC approach, but the choice of priors was guided by preliminary analyses involving a maximum likelihood approach.

Maximum likelihood estimations

One hundred optimization attempts were made for each tree in the sample.

MCMCs

Each MCMC involved 100,000,000 iterations of the chain, with the first 10,000,000 removed as burn-in. On the basis of the results of the maximum likelihood estimations, a reverse-jump hyperprior with an exponential distribution that can range between 0 and 10 was chosen for all analyses. A stepping-stone sampler with 100 stones was run for 100,000 iterations to estimate the log marginal likelihoods for the models in the posterior distribution of each analysis. All analyses were independently replicated three times, and each replication converged on highly similar rate and log marginal likelihood values (Supplementary Table 1).

Five models were tested (Fig. 4). In the full model, any transition between any two states was allowed. This allowed the analyses to select from all possible model structures. In the strong differentiation model, rates of transition from 0 to 2 (q02), 0 to 3 (q03) and 1 to 3 (q13) were set to zero. This constrained the analyses to include only models in which more differentiated authority structures evolved from less differentiated ones (1 → 2 → 3). In the strong unification model, rates of transition from 0 to 1 (q01), 0 to 2 (q02) and 3 to 1 (q31) were set to zero. This constrained the analyses to include only models in which less differentiated authority structures evolved from more differentiated ones (3 → 2 → 1). Since 2 (partly independent) is a more heterogeneous category than 0, 1 and 3, less stringent (weak) versions of the differentiation and unification models were also tested. In the weak differentiation model, only rates q02 and q03 were restricted to zero (that is, transitions from 1 to 3 were also allowed). In the weak unification model, only q01 and q02 were restricted to zero (that is, transitions from 3 to 1 were also allowed).

Model comparison

Support for the posterior distribution of analyses with different model structures was evaluated using log BFs calculated from the log marginal likelihoods obtained for each posterior distribution of models. Log BFs were interpreted following a scheme in which 0–2 is ‘not worth more than a bare mention’, 2–6 is ‘positive evidence’, 6–10 is ‘strong evidence’ and 10 or higher is ‘very strong evidence’58.

Reporting summary

Further information on research design is available in the Nature Research Reporting Summary linked to this article.