Introduction

The dynamic system represented by game Rock, Paper, Scissors (RPS) is both a physical reality in the animal world (specifically amongst three species of side-blotched lizards1) and serves as an important paradigm for assessing the degree of rational decision making inherent within non-cooperative environments across species (e.g.2,3). In a typical RPS game, participants reveal a three-alternative choice at the same time: Rock, Paper or Scissors. The winner (and loser) is calculated by the rule Rock wins over Scissors (the Scissors are ‘blunted’), Paper wins over Rock (the Rock is ‘covered’) and Scissors wins over Paper (the Paper is ‘cut’). The specific relationships between elements (non-transitive dominance relations4) dictate a crucial aspect of the game space, in that there is no singular strategy that guarantees success (or evolutionarily stable strategy; Maynard-Smith & Price, 1973, cited in3). As such, when it is played in a potentially infinitely recursive manner, the various responses may enjoy periods of temporary dominance and the lack of a definitive strategy becomes particularly apparent when children can often serve as formidable opponents to adults5.

One aspect of the game that has received particular interest results from the unique Nash equilibrium of RPS5, where “an equilibrium point is a pair of strategies that are best replies to each other, a best reply being a strategy that maximizes a player’s payoff, given the strategy chosen by the other player” (3, p. 140). During RPS, players should adopt a mixed-strategy equilibrium wherein multiple items are played stochastically2. In other words, each of the three items should be played with random distribution but equal probability (33.33%). The disadvantages of not following this strategy are made clear by6, who show that if a computer opponent plays one item more often than another (e.g., Rock) then human participants will play the appropriate counter-item with increased frequency (e.g., Paper). Under this scheme, the computer opponent would be said to be playing a strategy that could be dominated and serves as an example of irrational (not to mention evolutionarily unsound3) decision making. Therefore, precisely constructed game environments such as RPS supply researchers with a baseline against which deviations from rational decision-making may be observed and predicted. As7 (p. 55) state: “equilibrium strategies specified by game theory provide a precise yardstick to quantify how human behaviors deviate from the normative predictions for rational players. One can therefore try to identify factors responsible for the discrepancy between the normative predictions and observed behaviors”.

The first indication of irrationality in RPS comes from the observation that specific items in game systems may be naturally favoured. Decision making can be influenced by saliency8, where primary salience refers to selecting responses that more readily come to mind (c.f., availability heuristic9) and secondary salience refers to adopting a strategy whereby one assume the opponent is operating on the basis of primary salience. Evidence of primary salience in RPS comes from10 who reported that across 300 rounds, participants selected Rock 35.66%, Paper 32.12% and Scissors 32.23% of the time and a similar bias for Rock was also reported by4 with Rock 36%, Paper 33% and Scissors 32%. Therefore, there might be a simple influence at the item level that draws individuals away from adhering to a mixed-strategy equilibrium and, ultimately, rationality3. Similarly, secondary salience might also contribute to RPS performance according to the observations of6: my opponent is predominantly playing Rock so I will predominantly play Paper. However, such strategies cannot be evolutionarily stable due to the recursive nature of the game: eventually an opponent may eventually adjust their strategy according to your overplaying of Paper.

Ref. 4 also showed that participants implement an apparently successful rule-based strategy of if I win then I stay with my current item, if I lose then I shift to a new item (‘win-stay, lose-shift’; see also7, for a similar strategy in monkeys). In contrast to the memorial and cognitive demands of the mixed-strategy equilibrium (frequency counting three-alternative choices across hundreds of rounds to ensure that each item is played 33.33% of the time), tendencies to adopt rules like ‘win-stay, lose-shift’ become “psychologically plausible for human subjects with bounded rationality” 4(p. 5). Principles such as Thorndike’s Law of Effect (Thorndike, 1911, cited in11) and the matching law (Hernstein, 1961, cited in6), where the proportion of response matches the degree of reinforcement, seem to fit well with an account where participants maintain their current course of action in the light of success (‘win-stay’) but change their current course of action in the light of failure (‘lose-shift’; see also12, for a similar criterion of progress in the context of problem solving). Although necessary on the basis of limited human cognition, predictable consequences as a function of winning (reinforcement; stay) or losing (punishment; switch) also run the risk of being dominated. Furthermore, neural activity associated with reinforcement and punishment in the context of RPS trial outcome are found throughout the cortex and to a much larger degree than previously thought, with additional specific areas distinguishing between win and loss (accumbens, caudial ACC and transverse temporal region) and also between stay and switch (medial frontal cortex and caudate13). The cortex-encompassing activity associated with trial outcome has the required distributed nature to impact on numerous cognitive processes.

However, switch heuristics such as win-stay lose-shift remain underspecified at the level of item selection and two additional categories of response change suggest themselves (after4). First, participants may choose to downgrade their response across trials, defined as selecting the item in trial n + 1 that would have been beaten by their item at trial n (e.g., Rock followed by Scissors; also ‘descending’14 or ‘left-shift’15). Alternatively, participants may choose to upgrade their response across trials, defined as selecting the item in trial n + 1 that would have beaten their item at trial n (e.g., Rock followed by Paper; also ‘ascending’14 or ‘right-shift’15). Due to the cyclical nature of the relationships between items (see Fig. 1a) it would be possible to repeat the strategy of upgrading or downgrading across multiple consecutive trials. Of additional importance are the cognitive implications of draw trials, which are also currently underspecified. It may seem reasonable to assume that draw trials should be less arousing than win or loss trials and so have less on an impact on subsequent performance, but a recent study provided no evidence that this was the case13.

Figure 1
figure 1

(a) Schematic showing the cyclical nature of upgrading or downgrading responses in Rock, Paper, Scissors, (b) Graph showing strategy at trial n + 1 as a function of item selection at trial n, (c) Graph showing strategy at trial n + 1 as a function of outcome of trial n, (d) Graph showing the strategy adopted between trial n + 1 and n + 2 as a function of the strategy adopted between trial n and n + 1.

To further investigate the heuristics underlying RPS performance, human participants played 225 rounds of RPS with a computer opponent operating according to the mixed-strategy equilibrium. Human participants were not made aware of the specific strategy of the computer at the time of testing, given that the absence of instruction is important in understanding real-world decision making where information also tends to be incomplete6. Response proportions across consecutive trials were examined in terms of the item selected at trial n (Rock, Paper, Scissors), the outcome at trial n (win, lose, draw) and the strategy subsequently deployed at trial n + 1 relative to n (stay, upgrade, downgrade). The distribution of responses across three trials were also examined in terms of the strategy deployed between trial n and n + 1 (after4) and between trial n + 1 and n + 2 (stay, upgrade, downgrade). Any interactions revealed between these levels would undermine the view of human decision making as rational and, importantly, define the item-based and outcome-based conditions under which such violations could be predicted.

Results

Trial n item selection and outcome

Concerns regarding the violation of normality in the data set were addressed by carrying out arc-sine transformations on the proportion data, according to the suggestion of16. The formula 2*(ASIN(SQRT(x)) was used when proportion error rates were greater than zero and x represents the proportion, and, 2*(ASIN(SQRT(1/2 y))) was used when proportion error rates were equal to zero and y represented the number of possible observations within a cell. The main effects and interactions of the transformed data were equivalent to those generated by the original proportion data. To aid the interpretation of the descriptive statistics, we have retained the primary analysis of proportion data here although both the results from the transformed data and raw proportion data can be found in Supplementary Materials.

Using separate one-way repeated measures ANOVAs with the factors of item selection at trial n (rock, paper, scissors) and outcome at trial n (win, lose, draw), respectively, we confirm that participants did not significantly differ in terms of their item selection at trial n [F(2, 60) = 1.64, MSE = 368.53, p = 0.203, ηp2 = 0.052] or the outcome at trial n [F(2, 60) = 1.21, MSE = 94.85, p = 0.306, ηp2 = 0.039]. In terms of item selection at trial n, there was a non-significant tendency for participants to play Rock (80.10 trials; 35.60%) slightly more often than Paper (72.55 trials; 32.24%) or Scissors (72.35 trials; 32.16%). In terms of outcome at trial n, participants had a non-significant tendency to win (77.10 trials; 34.27%) slightly more than they drew (73.32 trials; 32.59%) or lost (74.58 trials; 33.15%).

First-order repetition effects

Proportion data using 222 trials (the first trial in each block had no previous history) were analysed according to a three-way repeated measures ANOVA using the factors of item selection at trial n (rock, paper, scissors), outcome at trial n (win, lose, draw) and strategy at trial n + 1 (stay, downgrade, upgrade). Since the strategy at trial n + 1 data were calculated as proportion of both item selection at trial n and outcome at trial n, the analysis of these trial n terms (and the resultant interaction) was meaningless (p = 1). The main effect of strategy was not significant [F(2, 60) = 2.70, MSE = 0.183, p = 0.075, ηp2 = 0.083], nor was the three-way interaction between item x outcome x strategy [F(8, 240) = 1.59, MSE = 0.012, p = 0.127, ηp2 = 0.050]. However, significant two-way interactions between item x strategy [F(4, 120) = 2.71, MSE = 0.048, p = 0.033, ηp2 = 0.083] and outcome x strategy [F(4, 120) = 6.71, MSE = 0.061, p < 0.001, ηp2 = 0.183] were observed. Figure 1b shows strategy at trial n + 1 as a function of item selection at trial n, which was decomposed according to Tukey’s HSD test (p < 0.05). Playing Rock at trial n did not seem to impact on strategy at trial n + 1, following Paper participants were more likely to switch (either upgrading or downgrading; numerically more likely for downgrading) than to stay and after Scissors there was a preference for switching (specifically upgrading) relative to staying.

Figure 1c shows strategy at trial n + 1 as a function of outcome at trial n, which was again decomposed according to Tukey’s HSD test (p < 0.05). No significant differences in trial n + 1 strategy were observed following a win although numerically the data were in favour of staying. In contrast, a loss more likely prompted item switching than staying (numerically in favour of item downgrading) and following a draw, participants were inclined to switch and specifically upgrade their item relative to staying.

Second-order repetition effects

Proportion data using 219 trials (the first 2 trials in each block had no immediate second-order history) were analysed according to a two-way repeated measures ANOVAs using the factors of strategy at trial n + 1 (stay, downgrade, upgrade) and strategy at trial n + 2 (stay, downgrade, upgrade). Proportion data was calculated from strategy at trial n + 1 rendering that main effect meaningless (p = 1). An interaction between strategy at trial n + 1 and n + 2 was revealed [F(4, 120) = 13.12, MSE = 0.012, p < 0.001, ηp2 = 0.304] in the absence of a main effect of strategy at trial n + 2 [F(2, 60) = 2.19, MSE = 0.063, p = 0.121, ηp2 = 0.068]. As shown in Fig. 1d and decomposed using Tukey’s HSD test (p < 0.05), staying with item selection between trial n and n + 1 failed to impact on the strategy adopted between trial n + 1 and n + 2. However, participants who upgraded were more likely to continue upgrading and participants who downgraded were more likely to continue downgrading.

Discussion

Human participants played RPS against a computer opponent with a mixed-strategy equilibrium2,5. Therefore, any deviation from the equal play of each of the three items (Rock, Paper, Scissors) and any predictable change in strategy (stay, upgrade, downgrade) as a function of the outcome of the previous trial (win, lose, draw) would place the human participant in a potentially exploitable position. The data provide only limited evidence of primary salience8 in the context of RPS, but nevertheless replicate the observations of4,10,14 in terms of participants’ tendency to overplay Rock. In terms of the origin of this effect, anecdotally some participants (and indeed some researchers) intuitively believed that Rock was somehow ‘better’ or ‘stronger’ that its Paper and Scissors counterparts, despite the fact that this assumption exists nowhere in the structure of the game. Future research examining both personal reinforcement history and connotative meaning17 of individual items in RPS might help to account for the subjective assumptions associated with favored items. If there is a tendency for Rock to be overplayed, then slightly overplaying Paper might be a sensible option against any future opponent6. However, since RPS has no evolutionarily stable strategy if the game is played iteratively5 the success of this strategy can only be short lived. Interestingly, human participants’ approximation of a mixed-strategy equilibrium in the light of their opponent playing the same strategy runs contrary to the performance of rhesus monkeys. In a simpler matching-pennies games7, monkeys adopted a mixed-strategy equilibrium only when the computer’s algorithm adjusted its strategy according to the frequency distribution of the monkey (secondary salience8). When the computer played according to a mixed-strategy equilibrium, monkeys deviated from equilibrium. Such decision-making differences between animals and humans are common and often reflect superior performance in the former (e.g.18 for pigeons’ enhanced sensitivity to base-rate information19 for pigeons’ improved performance at the Monty Hall problem). Given that decision-making is also partly determined by whether participants believe their opponent to be a human or machine20,21, perceived agency continues to be a critical avenue for future human and animal research.

In terms of the inter-trial analysis, the data both replicate and give increased specificity to the ‘win-stay, lose-shift’ strategy. Although consistent with behaviourist principles, the implementation of such a potentially dominated heuristic in recursive, non-cooperative environments places the user in an evolutionarily unsound position. As seen in Fig. 1c, there was a non-significant tendency to stay with the previous item selection following a win and to switch (more specifically, downgrade) item selection following a loss15. Such data are consistent with classic behaviourist principles where reinforced responses are more likely to be used again (‘win-stay’) and non-reinforced responses are less likely to be used again (‘lose-shift’). However, despite the RPS game space assigning equivalent weight to winning or losing (relative to drawing), gains and losses of equivalent magnitude do not necessarily have the same subjective value22. That is, the magnitude of difference between the three potential strategies was larger following loss than win trials. Therefore, consistent with the initial ideas of22, a loss impacts on rational decision making to a greater degree than a win and individuals become more predictable (and therefore more vulnerable) in terms of their strategy following a loss trial. Drawing with an opponent leads to the same overall strategic consequence than losing (i.e., switch) and so in this respect both losing and drawing may index a lack of reinforcement and an unsuccessful outcome (c.f.13). However, the subsequent nature of the switch is qualitatively different23: losing promotes downgrading whereas drawing promotes upgrading. Furthermore, those tendencies to upgrade or downgrade were perpetuated across three consecutive trials (Fig. 1d) lend credence to the idea that there also can be repetition in the nature of change and that these different forms of switch may have quite different cognitive and emotional consequences. This signposts future work examining how specific emotions may determine movement away from rational decision making (see24 for a review) and the trial-to-trial bases on which these occur (see25 for an exploration of regret aversion on consecutive decision making).

Of final interest are the implications of the lack of a significant three-way interaction between item selection at trial n, outcome at trial n and strategy at trial n + 1 during first-order repetition effect analysis. Comparing the data across Fig. 1c,d, one can see that both item selection at trial n and outcome at trial n had very similar impacts on strategy at trial n + 1. To summarize an additive model of trial n + 1 strategy that combines item selection and outcome at trial n, it is possible to select the item at trial n and outcome at trial n that produce the largest proportion of responses for each strategy at trial n + 1. Stay responses were associated with selecting Rock relative to Paper or Scissors and winning relative to losing or drawing, upgrade responses were associated with selecting Scissors and drawing, whereas downgrade responses were associated with picking Paper and losing. It is critical to note that in all 3 cases, item selection for the participant at trial n + 1 reliably predicts Rock: participant stay with Rock at trial n + 1 following a win, Paper is downgraded (to Rock) following a loss and Scissors are upgraded (also to Rock) following a draw. This final observation reveals a much more surprising (and actually much simpler) rule. Unpacking all three contingencies point to the likelihood that if the computer played Scissors on trial n the participant would be more likely to play Rock on trial n + 1, irrespective of the item selection and outcome at trial n. This might explain the non-significant tendency for participants to play Rock overall.

It is worth noting that, although consistent with previous literature, some of observed effects are small and there may be at least two reasons why this may be so. First, in contrast to other RPS investigations where individuals played a number of opponents4,10, here each participant played only one computerized opponent who acted according to the Nash equilibrium. It has been suggested that in a two-player RPS game, conditional probabilities should only show minor deviation from 33%26. Furthermore, the use of a computerized opponent who failed to take advantage of any player’s vulnerability may have also contributed to a fairly conservative test of irrational decision making. We are currently building various computerized versions of RPS strategy that take into account the player’s actions to varying degrees and we expect this will accentuate the deviations observed in the current data. Second, there was no additional consequence to winning, losing or drawing, other than the immediate feedback presented on screen. We are sensitive to the fact that the financial conversion of performance may well implicate different levels of activity at specific neural sites (such as the nucleus accumbens) from those associated with simple cognitive feedback [e.g.27]. We expect to see greater differentiation between win and loss trials when these are associated with a point and/or monetary system.

The enduring appeal of RPS is partly due to the failure to reveal any optimal strategy when the game is played recursively. Indeed, any collective strategies revealed here (e.g., overplay of Rock, ‘win-stay, lose-shift’, recursive upgrading and downgrading) could be used by the most savvy RPS player in the development of suitable counter-strategies. As such, the RPS framework continues to evolve but remains stable in providing critical insights how we deviate from rational decision making. The present study identifies two negative trial outcomes (losing and drawing) that make irrational decisions more likely, with each outcome leading to different behavioural change (downgrading and upgrading). Such strategies are also more likely to be perpetuated across multiple trial outcomes, assumedly as a result of the constraints of human information processing. Revealed through the game space of RPS, the tendency to initiate any form of potentially dominated strategy as a result of the micro-emotional responses associated with negative outcome may have more serious implications in other continuous non-cooperative interactions such as economics and politics.

Method

Participants

31 undergraduate students (26 female) participated in the study; mean age was 20.23 years (SD = 5.66; one participant did not provide their age) and 27 were right-handed. 2 additional participants were excluded for recording responses at each trial using paper and pencil, assumedly in a systematic attempt to work out the computer’s strategy. Relative to the other participants who used internal working memory only, we felt this did not represent the same test of bounded rationality. The study was approved for testing by the Research Ethics Board of Ryerson University and the study was carried out in accordance with the approved guidelines. Informed consent was obtained from all participants and course credit was offered for participation.

Stimuli and apparatus

Visual representations of a hand making Rock, Paper and Scissors signs sourced from the internet were displayed at a visual angle of approximately 4.5° × 4.5° with participants sat approximately 57 cms away from the screen. All text was white and presented on black background. The presentation of stimuli was controlled by PsyScope (Cohen, MacWhinney, Flatt & Provost, 1993) and responses were recorded using a PsyScope Button Box. The PsyScope script is available upon request.

Design and procedure

Following a set of specific on-screen instructions (see Supplementary Materials), participants completed 225 trials of RPS separated across 3 blocks of 75 trials. In each block, the computer played Rock, Paper and Scissors 25 times in a random order (mixed-strategy equilibrium2,3,7). At each trial, participants were prompted to press one of three buttons corresponding to Rock, Paper and Scissors, following the signal ‘GO!’ At the time of pressing, the computer displayed their selection on the left, the participant’s selection on the right for 1000 ms. After a response checking period of 100 ms, feedback was provided for a further 1000 ms as to whether the participant won, lost or drew the trial. The next trial started following a 250 ms blank screen. Participants were verbally informed that the computer would play in a certain way (which would be revealed after the experiment) and that they were to try to beat the computer across the course of the game. Prior to RPS completion, participants completed a short mental exercise which was designed to manipulate the perceived agency of the computer (see Supplementary Materials). Since this manipulation appeared unsuccessful, data were collapsed across agency.

Additional Information

How to cite this article: Dyson, B. J. et al. Negative outcomes evoke cyclic irrational decisions in Rock, Paper, Scissors. Sci. Rep. 6, 20479; doi: 10.1038/srep20479 (2016).