Skip to main content

Thank you for visiting nature.com. You are using a browser version with limited support for CSS. To obtain the best experience, we recommend you use a more up to date browser (or turn off compatibility mode in Internet Explorer). In the meantime, to ensure continued support, we are displaying the site without styles and JavaScript.

Segregating socioeconomic classes leads to an unequal redistribution of wealth

Subjects

Abstract

Social living groups are organised in social hierarchies often exhibiting inequalities in beings. Investigating class segregation and the use of punishment applied downward in the rank acts as a key aspect to ascertain how dominant and subordinate partners cooperate to achieve mutual profit. In human subjects coming from countries with an uneven wealth distribution, this mutual profit may be reduced, especially for the lower socioeconomic classes. We implemented an Iterated Prisoner’s Dilemma Game experiment in one such country with starkly high inequality, China. We split relatively richer and poorer subjects into separate classes and gave only one the authority to punish the other. When rich subjects could unidirectionally punish poor subjects (as in a segregated society), rich subjects decreased their cooperation effort while punishing poor subjects. When rich and poor subjects, instead, could punish each other in random combinations (as in an integrated society) they decreased defections so they could punish more. In the segregated society model, the punishing classes earned twice as much as the non-punishers. Conversely, in the integrated society model, weak differences in earnings were found, leading to a decrease in inequality. These results were confirmed by an agent-based simulation mirroring the human experiments and repeated during a very large number of rounds. From our research, we conclude that, especially in developing economies, if the states enacted that the dominant and subordinate individuals relinquished their almost segregated state, this would lead to a redistribution of wealth and power.

Introduction

Animal and human societies are organised in multiple layers and clusters with ingrained socioeconomic classes bearing inequalities that have been the target of interest of scholars for decades (Landtman, 1934). From 10,000 years ago to today, human societies have greatly changed due to the shift from hunting and gathering to farming, and to industrialisation. Many impute the appearance of these hierarchical levels to the emergence of agriculture and the formation of larger and more complex societies (e.g. Fix, 2019; Landtman, 1934; Lee, 1990). Others, instead, believe they were always present (e.g. David-Barrett and Dunbar, 2012, 2013), as if hierarchy inevitably appears in larger groups whose individuals display more complex interactions.

The nature of social relationships in which cooperative or defective individuals typically engage, both in nature and within human societies, is commonly ruled by an asymmetric use of power exerted by most individuals (Ames, 2007; Boehm, 1999; Chapais, 2015; Cohen, 1998; Keltner et al., 2003; Mattison et al., 2016; Pansini, 2012; van Vugt and Tybur, 2015). We are aware that the individuals’ unequal resource holdings affect, (unwittingly, Hauser et al., 2019) the willingness to cooperate at a given time (in empirically tested subjects, which also holds true in nature: Burton-Chellew et al., 2013; Cronin et al., 2015; Frank, 1996, 2010; Gavrilets and Fortunato, 2014; Herrmann et al., 2019; Pansini, 2011; Suchak et al., 2016; with different states’ economic systems: Acemoglu et al., 2017; in international joint ventures: Inkpen and Beamish, 1997). Moreover, these inequalities also affect future expectations in iterated exchange (Zeng et al., 2019). Therefore, when inter-hierarchical exchanges occur, the exercise of power alters the initial, hypothetical centrality of the game, with an eventual shift of the strategies of the players towards disjoint interests (Barker et al., 2015; Campennì and Schino, 2016; Cox et al., 2013; Herbst et al., 2017; Phillips, 2017; Wang et al., 2010) and, eventually, a decreased drive to engage into any deal.

Already depicted by Hume more than three centuries ago (Hume, 1975), at the heart of this reluctance to interact may lie a lack of reciprocal trust (Greif and Tabellini, 2010; Steckermeier and Delhey, 2018; Xin, 2017) of the poorer and richer classes of individuals who eventually prefer not to enter into transactions with each other. As a result, the civic engagement and higher political participation of lower classes is prevented (Uslaner, 2005) with detrimental impacts on the countries’ economies (Algan and Cahuc, 2014; Benabou, 1996; Bowles, 2012; Horváth, 2013).

Socioeconomic class segregation appears right in those societies with a high rate of income inequality (Axtell et al., 2001; Henrich and Boyd, 2008; Smith and Choi, 2007). Modelling the behaviour of individuals coming from such economic constellations allows us to better scrutinise human cooperation at an evolutionary level (Bowles et al., 2014), such as, for example during times when states have not yet implemented thorough wealth redistribution policies (Joyce and Xu, 2019).

Although behavioural economics research has traditionally focussed on the factors that determine the individuals’ choices between cooperation and defection, researchers have widened the perspective by including punishment as a further strategy to induce cooperation in unwilling partners (in the case of repeated social interactions, e.g.: Boyd and Richerson, 1992; Dreber et al., 2008; Fehr and Gachter, 2002; West et al., 2007; Yamagishi, 1986; conversely, rewards can also be computed in a game, e.g.: Jusup et al., 2018). A number of examples have been found by ethologists in nature whereby several species display punishment providing the individuals with an option to attempt increasing their own fitness (Clutton-Brock and Parker, 1995), but whether or not this behaviour prompts a higher use of cooperation or, rather, retaliation is still a question open to debate in humans and other species (Baldassarri and Grossman, 2011; Balliet et al., 2011; Baumard, 2010; Bone et al., 2016; Boyd et al., 2010; Dong et al., 2019; Fehr and Gachter, 2002; Fehr and Schurtenberger, 2018; Fowler et al., 2005; Gächter et al., 2008; Gao et al., 2015; Hilbe et al., 2014; Janssen and Bushman, 2008; Li et al., 2018; Nikiforakis, 2008; Raihani and Bshary, 2015; Raihani et al., 2012; Riehl and Frederickson, 2016; Wubs et al., 2016).

When punishment is a strategy the subjects can enforce, asymmetric interests may become more apparent (in Public Good Games: Baldassarri and Grossman, 2011; Gächter et al., 2008; Kuwabara et al., 2016; O’Gorman et al., 2009; Reuben and Riedl, 2013; Vincent, 2017; in Prisoner’s Dilemma Games: Pansini et al., 2016) and the players’ final payoffs may be even further differentiated (Burton-Chellew et al., 2013; Gächter et al., 2017; Raihani et al., 2012). This may be the case especially when social classes are segregated, leaving it largely up to more powerful subjects to impose such a strategy over their less dominant partners. We therefore deemed it appropriate to include punishment in the analysis of inequalities.

For the first time after 12 years, in 2013, the Gini coefficient (measuring income inequality within countries) of the world most populous country of China has become publicly known (The Economist, 2012) presenting predictably high levels in the range of 0.53–0.55 (Xie and Zhou, 2014). Top scoring countries like South Africa, Brazil, and Nigeria fare at 0.4–0.6 Gini levels. More recent data, accessed from possibly biased governmental sources, report that the Gini index in 2015 stood at 0.462 and in 2016 at 0.465 (Jizhe, 2016). As the second richest nation in the world, their per capita income becomes the 58th country out of a 79 worldwide list positioning between Costa Rica and Brazil (Bloomberg, 2018). Although the negative effects of class segregations are well known in these countries, and 77% of Chinese respondent declare large concerns in this regard (Lockett, 2016; Wike and Stokes, 2016), we do not know of any empirical examples in behavioural economics literature and Prisoner’s Dilemma Games displaying how to lessen the individuals’ disparity in incomes. Recently, Bone and colleagues (2015) provided social dilemma game participants with different punishment powers. We chose a different approach here. In our experiment, we estimated and accounted for the participants’ socioeconomic background as a life history covariate determining their ability to punish or not punish the opponents.

In this paper, we model socioeconomic class segregation wherein individuals that are more dominant can exert punishment over less dominant ones. Our experiments and ensuing simulations were implemented in a country with a high rate of income inequality, China. We found that a redistribution of wealth could be attained only when both rich and poor subjects are allowed to punish each other. More specifically, we invited richer and poorer individuals to play a Prisoner’s Dilemma Game with a costly punishment option in both a segregated and an integrated condition. Steep differences were found in payoff gains in the segregated condition (rich people playing with poor ones), while no differences were found in the integrated condition (designed and implemented with random socioeconomic matching). To model the effect of punishment realistically, we imposed a simplified and skewed payoff strategy on the players, whereby in a first treatment only dominant and richer players were able to exert punishment on subordinate and poorer players. Later, we allowed only poorer subjects to punish richer ones instead. By doing so, we established two treatments to predict whether such segregated societies in relation to both punishment and socioeconomic status would have influenced changes in the players’ preferred strategies and payoff gains versus reference results of an integrated society. This hypothetical integrated society was the one we assumed giving rise to a redistribution of wealth.

Methods

Laboratory experiments

The experiments were performed at Yunnan University of Finance and Economics in Kunming, Yunnan province, China, with students still novel to game theory and behavioural economics tests.

Informed consent forms were submitted for all the anonymous participants in our research. The Yunnan University of Finance and Economics Ethics Committee approved all the experiments utilising human subjects, which, in turn, was carried out in accordance with the approved guidelines.

The experiments took place during 9 different days of November and December 2014 and of April 2015. The students’ age spanned from 18 to 22 and their geographical provenience varied across different parts of China. We tested a total of 348 students (164 males, 184 females). The same subject never took part in more than one experiment and that subjects had not previously participated in other behavioural experiments. Our analyses included 9 experimental sessions with three replicate sessions for each of the three game scenarios.

While sitting in a computer lab, the subjects were briefed in neutral terms regarding the rules of the Iterated Prisoner’s Dilemma Game. The experiment consisted of three, between-subject treatments. In each of them, the students were allocated to two different trading classes. In the CDP class, the subjects were free to choose between three strategies: cooperation, defection, and punishment (referred as A, B, and C to the students). In the CD class, they were only allowed to choose between two strategies: cooperation and defection. For simplicity, the exit option to terminate the interaction (Vanberg and Congleton, 1992) was not given to the players. The treatments were implemented as following: in T0 the subjects were assigned randomly to the CDP and CD class; in T1 richer students were assigned to the CDP class and poorer ones to the CD class; in T2 (the reverse of T1) poorer subjects could choose any option amongst CDP while the richer ones could opt only for CD. The treatments comprised a number of subjects so to be counterbalanced: T0 116 students, T1 122 students, and T3 110 students. The students were not informed of the socioeconomic principles, which we elected to offer them for the purposes of our research and why their options differed. They were simply informed that one group had the option of employing the extra strategy, namely, punishment.

The purpose of T1 is to simulate societies often found in developing countries with high Gini coefficients—with China at present providing an extreme example (Xie and Zhou, 2014). T2, contrastively, stand out as an unlikely scenario in which poor people can only punish people richer than them. This treatment helps ascertain some degree of causation arising between T0 and T1. That is, whether results can be interpreted simply via implementation of the segregation effect or whether the segregation effect combined with the social status influenced the outcome.

The payoff matrix as designated in the diagram below shows the outcome of the round of each game expressed in earned points. Upper and lower case letters indicate the reading order.

 player 2
CooperationDefection
PLAYER 1
 Cooperation1, 1
A, a
−1, 2
B, d
 Defection2, −1
C, b
0, 0
D, e
 Punishment1, −3
E, c
−1, −2
F, f

The values for defection and punishment in this experiment are lower than in Dreber et al. (2008) and Wu et al. (2009), largely due to the concerns raised by Rankin et al. (2009), who showed that assigning levels too high to defection may confound the players about the difference between these two game options.

We matched the individuals into dyads who had to repeatedly interact at successive rounds. We tallied an average of 82.5 iterated rounds per session and 22.4 interactions per session. During each round of interactions, two participants simultaneously chose between two or three available options (CD or CDP). At the completion of each round, each participant was shown his or her partner’s choice together with the total payoff scores. The experimental sessions averaged 38 participants each, up to 9 repeated interactions with the same dyad according to a 75% probability stopping rule (Dal Bó, 2005), with an average duration of each experiment of ~1 h (unknown to the players, to avoid end-game effects). At the end, each subject received an average payment of ¥53.64 Chinese renminbi.

At present in China there is no consistent criterion for assigning scholarships to students from lower income families. Thus, university enrolment offices are not aware of the precise socioeconomic status of their students. To obtain this information, we requested each student to fill an anonymous questionnaire supplying us with this indispensable data right before the start of the experiments. The questionnaire was answered electronically in the computer lab. From the students’ answers, we could assign each subject to the two classes while concomitantly applying the permissible strategies as per our methodology, either CDP or CD, by calculating the results of the questionnaire in the computer lab in real time with a precompiled algorithm. In particular, we asked students to provide basic demographic information focussing on their families’ income and other elements (reported in Supplementary Methods). The list included, how many houses their family owns (HOUSE#), how many cars (CAR#), how many rooms present in their first house divided by the number of family members (ROOM#/FAMMEMB#), their parents’ job type (JOB), and whether they have an undergraduate degree (BACDEG) (for the full list of questions, see Supplementary information). From their answers, we calculated an index in order to quantify where they stood along a variable socioeconomic class spectrum. This index was determined arbitrarily as

$$\begin{array}{l}{Y} = 2.5\,{\mathrm{HOUSE}}\# \, + \,2\,\left( {{\mathrm{CAR}}\# \, + \,1} \right)/{\mathrm{FAMMEMB}}\# \, + \\ 2\,\left( {\left( {{\mathrm{ROOM}}\# \, + \,1} \right)/{\mathrm{FAMMEMB}}\# } \right) + 1.5\left( {1.5\,{\mathrm{FATJOB}}} \right) + \\ {\mathrm{MOTJOB + FATBACDEG + MOTBACDEG}}\end{array}$$

We assigned different weights to these indicators of wealth, based on the common assumption that, in order of importance and weight (a) the possession of properties weighs more than the possession of cars, (b) a house with more rooms is more valuable because usually it is larger, (c) that parents with jobs as managers weight more than employees, and (d) parents graduated from university also contribute at increasing this socioeconomic index.

Using the results, we could rank and assign each subject to one of the two classes we created, splitting them according to whether their answers placed them below or above the median of their respective indexes.

Validation of the socioeconomic index

To validate whether the answers to the questionnaire were representative for ascribing the two student types to their actual socioeconomic classes, we checked whether individuals with higher scores were also those individuals earning more during the experiment. Due to their elevated socioeconomic background, we hypothesised that, in fact, they could have chosen more effective strategies and eventually earned more points (Bone et al., 2015; Holland et al., 2012; Nikiforakis et al., 2010). This hypothesis was confirmed by our sample, since the single students who earned relatively more within their experimental class division were those coming from a financially better off background (F1,266 = 4.84, p = 0.029) (Figs 1 and 2 in Supplementary Results).

Agent-based model

Following the lab experiment, we developed a set of Agent-based simulations to compare the simpler behaviour of agents with humans, when the former adopted similar or different strategies than the latter group. Adopting an Agent-based modelling approach, in fact, offers one significant advantage: the experimenters can test different hypotheses pertaining to the evolutionary and cognitive mechanisms needed to perform different behaviours (Campennì and Schino, 2014).

As in the segregation treatments of T1 and T2, we split the agents into two economic classes (rich and poor) and we assigned a group-dependent propensity in adopting a cooperative or defective behaviour.

The agents played according to the same payoff matrix adopted in the experiments with human subjects.

The first hypothesis we decided to test is whether the social status of the individuals affected their propensity to cooperate. In the model, in fact, we gave for granted that such phenomenon exists, due to the results originated from the human experiment. Our assumption was to ascertain if the fact that richer individuals may be more likely to cooperate was due to knowing they could rely on other people with more wealth. Poorer individuals, instead, may be more likely to play safe and defect because their life circumstances generally are more of need (Gächter et al., 2017; Piff et al., 2010). For this reason, in the first set of simulations we assigned a probability of p = 0.7 to the richer agents to cooperate or to the poorer to defect in the first rounds lacking prior information. Later, we decided to test a set of different hypotheses considering: (i) a scenario where there was no difference in belonging to one of the two classes and there was a generalised high propensity to perform defective acts in first rounds (i.e., p = 0.95 for all agents) (see Piff, 2014; Piff et al., 2012 for the scientific background which inspired this); and (ii) the size of the memory in the short memory condition, set to 5 instead of 10 rounds.

Statistical analysis

We acquired two types of empirical data relating to cooperation via z-Tree (Fischbacher, 2007). First, we learnt the proportions of CDP and CD chosen behaviours, and, secondly, we discovered the final payoffs gained by each student. These sets of data were analysed by generalised linear mixed models via R 3.2.4 (R Core Team, 2016) via the lmerTest package (Kuznetsova et al., 2015). The algorithm calculating the socioeconomic index was coded in IBM SPSS Statistics 24, as well as the graphs reported in this paper and its Supplementary information.

Results

Frequencies of cooperation, defection and punishment

To understand how the players behaved differently as a result of their division into the two CDP and CD classes, we obtained behavioural measures and derived the earnings from them. We used a GLMM with the frequencies of their choices (C, D, or P) as a dependent variable, implementing the split into the two trading classes by treatment as fixed effects while the subjects as random effects. (This GLMM is the reduced version of a more general one—reported in Supplementary information—incorporating several demographic and social characters obtained with a questionnaire reported in Supplementary information) Figure 1 shows the behavioural frequencies the players displayed. Belonging to either one of the trading classes significantly explained the variation in behavioural strategies (F1,347 = 49.15, p < 0.001). However, the integrated or segregated conditions proved to have no significant effect on the selection of strategies (F2,345 = 0.74, p = 0.47).

Fig. 1: Frequencies of Cooperation, Defection, and Punishment (C, D, P) across the three treatments.
figure1

In T0 the subjects could punish each other by random partner matching, regardless of their socioeconomic class (integrated society model); in T1 and T2 the matching was predetermined (segregated society models): in T1 richer subjects could punish poorer ones, whereas in T2 poorer could punish richer ones. High levels of defections are found in all treatments, but, in the integrated condition, the punishers limited themselves in defecting while punishing. In both segregation conditions, instead, the punishers decreased their cooperation levels when punishing. ** Means p < 0.01, *** means p < 0.001; error bars show standard errors of the means.

By analysing the differential frequencies of the students’ choices, we can infer the impact that punishment had on the players. In T0, the two classes cooperated at similar levels (t2,9518 = −0.47, p = 0.63). However, the 12.4% rate of punishment added to the 68.36% of defection makes up for the defection rate of the CD class not able to punish (F2,9518 = 4.21, p = 0.015). This indicates that, in the integrated condition, the punishers partly restrain themselves from defecting while punishing. In both T1 and T2, conversely, cooperation levels were significantly different across classes (F1,20510 = 266, p < 0.001) whereas defection levels were not (F2,20505 = 0.226, p = 0.79). Hence, in both segregation conditions the punishers decreased their cooperation levels when choosing to punish. For a finer representation of what happens during the behavioural exchanges between partners on a time scale (see Fig. 3 of Supplementary information).

Players’ earnings

One of the driving questions we mined our data for was whether the players earn differently as a result of their disparity in socioeconomic background. Moreover, did their incomes vary due to the condition that only some players were permitted to implement the punishment strategy? The treatments and class separation allowed for exploring such questions (as displayed in Fig. 2). In all three different conditions the total earnings achieved by the both classes combined were statistically in the same small range (T1 = 101; T2 = 102; T3 = 104 units + comparable SE’s). Thus, we can conclude that this manipulation, redistributing the subjects into the two distinct classes, did not cause a sizeable difference in total earnings.

Fig. 2: Final earnings the subjects obtained from the experiment (measured in Chinese renminbi).
figure2

In the segregated conditions, the subjects who could punish (CDP) earned double than what those who could not did (CD). (*) Means marginally significant, p = 0.048, *** means p < 0.001; error bars show standard errors of the means.

When comparing the treatments, we checked whether in the integrated condition the players earned differently. In this treatment, the players were randomly assigned to the two different classes regardless of their socioeconomic status. The ability to punish the players belonging to the other class made a marginal increase in earnings possible (of 11 points), which proved to be slightly statistically significant (t1,108 = 1999, p = 0.048). In the two segregation treatments, instead, it is readily apparent how the two classes of players differentiated their earnings. The punishers earned more, almost double as much as the other CD class (F1,229 = 147, p < 0.0001) regardless of the chosen treatment (F1,229 = 0.064, p = 0.8).

Agent-based model

Frequencies of Cooperation, Defection, and Punishment

We tested whether agents behaved differently due to: (i) their division into CDP and CD classes and ensuing ability to either perform only a subset of all possible actions (i.e., the CD class) or all possible actions (i.e., the CDP class); (ii) the different cognitive mechanisms involved in selecting to cooperate or to defect. Following this, we report results from a population of 350 agents, which is an analogous size to the students involved in the human experiments.

Before running the simulation which most closely resembles the behaviour displayed by the human subjects, we ran prior simulations to test for occurrences of a class-dependent predisposition of rich agents to behave as cooperators or defectors. Additionally, we also ran other simulations to test for the ability of the agents to remember past interactions (see Supplementary Results).

In the final set of simulations which we present here, we tested for a predisposition in all agents towards defection with p = 0.95 (for a general predisposition to defect, see Piff, 2014; Piff et al., 2012), exclusively implementing a short-term memory strategy. In this case, the number of past round outcomes each agent could remember was fixed at 5. The simulation shows that defection is the preferred behaviour performed most often by the agents (Fig. 3—for additional analyses with 80 rounds, 1000 agents and different strategies depending on varying memory size, see Figs 46 in Supplementary information).

Fig. 3: Behavioural frequencies of Cooperation, Defection and Punishment (C, D, P) shown by the agents in the Agent Based model with a memory size equal to five rounds.
figure3

Defection levels were lower and cooperation was higher compared to the human experiment. The predisposition to defect at first encounter is 95%. N = 350 agents. Supplementary information reports similar results with a larger number of agents, different memory sizes and different strategies. The minute error bars show standard error of the mean values with 95% confidence interval.

In T0 and T1 we can see the artificial agents performed behaviours similar to what the human did, with the exception of a generally higher propensity to cooperate. In T2, though, when agents adopted a Tit-for-Tat strategy, the agents from the class of rich agents selected less punishment; further, when agents adopted a short-term memory strategy, instead (i.e., they were enabled to use outcome information from the preceding five interactions), agents from both classes clearly chose to defect more and to cooperate less. Finally, when the agents adopted an incremental memory strategy, there is a small increase in defection performed by agents from both classes (see Supplementary information for all these results). This combination of parameters, (i.e., short-term memory strategy and T2 treatment with a strong propensity to perform defective acts for agents from both classes) led to results remarkably similar to those obtained from the human experiments with Chinese students. Consequently, the models proved sound since a varying group size does not lead to any variation in the results.

Agents’ earnings

For the computerised simulations, we consider here a generalised predisposition to defect of p = 0.95 and with a short memory size consisting of five previous rounds. In T0, the agents from both classes tallied the same amount of earnings. In T1, the richer agents earned double of the poorer agents. In T2, the richer agents earned more than double the amount of the poorer agents (see Fig. 4 for details). For additional analyses about earning (see Figs 79 in Supmentary information).

Fig. 4: Agent Based model final earnings agents obtained from the simulation with a memory size of five rounds.
figure4

In the integration treatment, the agents who could punish (CDP) earned the same amount that those who could not did (CD). In the segregated treatments, those that could punish earned approximately double of those who could not. These results are in line with those of the human experiments. The predisposition to defect in such cases at first encounter is 95%. N = 350 agents. Supplementary information reports similar results with a larger number of agents, different memory sizes and different strategies. The minute error bars show standard error rates of the mean values with a 95% confidence interval.

Discussion

The discipline of economics has historically looked at the effects of income distribution on overall economic growth, essentially taking the position that while a more equal distribution of income might indeed benefit society, any policy efforts to promote redistribution do exact an overall cost (e.g. Benabou, 2000). However, if the risk-taking for anonymous cooperation is deterred by income inequality (Brosnan and Bshary, 2016) leading to the formation of segregated groups within the same society, this overall cost might be balanced out.

We allowed for the evolution of behavioural exchanges when relatively richer and poorer individuals were let interact within the context of a Prisoner’s Dilemma Game. Selecting the subjects from a country where the distribution of wealth is plainly uneven and in which socioeconomic classes are just as evidently distinct (Triandis, 1995; Xie and Zhou, 2014), we were interested in examining how this state of socioeconomic segregation alters the anonymous subjects’ behaviour and their incomes. In the treatment modelling an integrated society, the subjects could freely trade points across socioeconomic classes. In the more realistic models of socioeconomic class segregation, the classes were permitted to alternatively interact from one class to the other. In all treatments, the use of punishment could be realistically carried out by only one class. Comparing the treatments, we could ascertain that the behavioural and monetary differences we eventually found were principally due to the effect of socioeconomic segregation.

The class division we implemented caused a difference in the final earnings gained by the players, whether they interacted in a segregated or integrated socioeconomic condition. In the segregated models with people and artificial agents, final incomes amounted to an increase of just over 90% in favour of the class of individuals or agents that were provided with the option to punish others. Social inequality therefore increased after the experiments. However, in the integrated model, the incomes proved to be, statistically, only modestly dissimilar for the human subjects, which also produced the same result in the computer simulations. There were no differences in the amounts of cooperation, defection, and punishment behaviours of rich and poor individuals in the segregated societies (T1 with T2). We therefore conclude people and agents from both backgrounds do not implement punishment according to social learning and life experience in their different milieus to gain any further.

By splitting the anonymous players according to their different socioeconomic classes, we brought about behavioural changes in subjects who were not aware of the social status of the other partners (similar to Kuwabara et al., 2016). These two elements lead us to conclude that it is precisely the integration effect that allows for a redistribution of wealth. Firstly, by alternating encounters between partners with similar or different socioeconomic origins, they could balance out their earnings and, secondly, the use of intra-class punishment (rich versus rich, and poor versus poor) may well also narrow the gap related to different final payoff earnings (a larger sample size, within group, should provide these meaningful statistics in a follow-up study). Furthermore, the simulations suggested that the strategy adopted by our subjects relied on the memory of the five preceding rounds. It seems therefore that players adjust their strategies to mostly defect during these initial exchanges. A prevalence for defection by Chinese subjects is not a novel to our study, but rather a feature previously noted by other authors (e.g. Pansini et al., 2016; Wu et al., 2009), probably to be imputed to the fact that only 11.3% of Chinese trust a person whom they met for the first time, compared to about 38% in the West (Greif and Tabellini, 2010) and that in China the level of trust toward strangers is <40%, whereas in the U.S. it is over 60% (Inglehart et al., 1998).

By focussing on the ability to punish, an option realistically more frequently opted for downward in the social hierarchy than upward, we showed how disparity in socioeconomic classes does not cause a modification in cooperative behaviours per se. (It should be noted that the students not able to punish might have been affected in their behaviours by the threat of being punished, irrespective of the actual use of punishment employed by their more powerful partners: Bone et al., 2015; Fehr and Gachter, 2002). Rather than allowing the subjects to themselves punish their partners, a different game could be implemented by giving the authority to designated individuals or a centralised authority to use second-order punishment, as performed in those Public Good Games of Hilbe et al. (2014) and Baldassarri and Grossman (2011) (As it stands, this experiment can be compared to other IPD games in similar anonymous player conditions. However, another game scenario would need evaluation if we inform the subjects (Xie et al., 2017) about their reciprocal social status (Cherry et al., 2005; Zhang et al., 2020)).

Our results are somewhat different from previous research, which concluded that members of different socioeconomic classes were found cooperating in their own ways (Holland et al., 2012; Wilson et al., 2009). In these two studies, for instance, people from lower socioeconomic classes offered less than the wealthy ones in donation experiments due to their perceived higher relative cost of cooperation. Furthermore, in the Bone et al. study (2015), students were given different punishing powers and, as a result, the weaker subjects also wound up investing less. In our case, by contrast, the investments made by the poorer subjects fared at the same levels of the richer ones. Access to higher education is, in fact, a relatively recent phenomenon in China and, unlike in the UK or US (Bone et al., 2015; Holland et al., 2012; Wilson et al., 2009), tuition fees are always subsidised here, making our ‘poorer’ subjects probably better off. Yet, the experiment took place in Yunnan province, which is the second poorest province (Bloomberg, 2018) with an inequality issue likely larger than the country’s average. Regardless of the absolute wealth of the subjects, what counts is the relative gap amongst them. When considering the pre-experiment wealth conditions of these individuals, given how, due to punishment, the poorer ones can earn more than the rich (in T2), inequalities are overall potentially reduced by favouring the poor individuals who seem to have the ability to achieve power hastily.

Through the differential use of punishment, we modelled how a redistribution of wealth can be achieved following some of the principles of the Keynesian approach to a free-market economy between the states (see Bardhan et al., 2006; Bowles, 2012). In a more base and practical sense, state systems in high Gini-coefficient countries should seek to implement practical measures and act decisively to foster a decrease in the yawning gap in socioeconomic classes. Regardless of its impressive and top line economic development, China should consider enacting reforms (e.g. Jacobs and Mazzucato, 2016; Scheffer et al., 2017) in pursuit of this critical goal. We believe that fostering the integration of economic exchanges (Acemoglu et al., 2017; Benabou, 1996) and enlarging network exchanges (Bowles et al., 2014; David-Barrett and Dunbar, 2013; Kets et al., 2011; Wang et al., 2015; Xia et al., 2015) are key elements for the future progress of developing economies. Our study shows an alternative pathway for the evolution of social integration and redistribution (yet with a very simple design, similar to what now even seen in the redistribution of unequal resources by mutualistic bacterias (Whiteside et al., 2019)), departing from individuals who adjust their social position by levelling out their earnings. Via this approach, though, the older Confucian approach separating people into distinct classes (Greif and Tabellini, 2010) shall be progressively superseded by the old saying that a chain is only as strong as its weakest link.

Data availability

The data are available upon request.

References

  1. Acemoglu D, Robinson JA, Verdier T (2017) Asymmetric growth and institutions in an interdependent world. J Political Econ 125:1245–1305. https://doi.org/10.1086/693038

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. Algan Y, Cahuc P (2014) Chapter 2—Trust, growth, and well-being: new evidence and policy implications. In: Aghion P, Durlauf SN (Eds) Handbook of economic growth. Elsevier, pp. 49–120

  3. Ames K (2008) The archaeology of rank. Handbook of archaeological theories. Rowman & Littlefield, pp. 487–513

  4. Axtell RL, Epstein JM, Young HP (2001) The emergence of classes in a multiagent bargaining model. Social Dynamics 27:191–211

  5. Baldassarri D, Grossman G (2011) Centralized sanctioning and legitimate authority promote cooperation in humans. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 108: 11023–11027. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1105456108

  6. Balliet D, Mulder LB, Van Lange PA (2011) Reward, punishment, and cooperation: a meta-analysis. Psychol Bull 137:594

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. Bardhan PK, Bowles S, Wallerstein M (2006) Globalization and egalitarian redistribution. Princeton University Press

  8. Barker JL, Loope KJ, Reeve HK (2015) Asymmetry within social groups: division of labor and intergroup competition. J Evolut Biol 29:560–571. https://doi.org/10.1111/jeb.12805

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Baumard N (2010) Has punishment played a role in the evolution of cooperation? A critical review. Mind Soc 9:171–192. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11299-010-0079-9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Benabou R (1996) Inequality and growth. NBER Macroecon Annu 11:11–74. https://doi.org/10.2307/3585187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Benabou R (2000) Unequal societies: income distribution and the social contract. Am Econ Rev 90:96–129

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Bloomberg (2018) China’s got a $46,000 wealth gap problem Bloomberg

  13. Boehm C (1999) Hierarchy in the forest: the evolution of egalitarian behavior. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  14. Bone JE, Wallace B, Bshary R, Raihani NJ (2015) The effect of power asymmetries on cooperation and punishment in a prisoner’s dilemma game. PLoS ONE 10:e0117183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Bone JE, Wallace B, Bshary R, Raihani NJ (2016) Power asymmetries and punishment in a prisoner’s dilemma with variable cooperative investment. PLoS ONE 11:e0155773. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0155773

    CAS  Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  16. Bowles S (2012) The new economics of inequality and redistribution. Cambridge University Press

  17. Bowles S, Loury GC, Sethi R (2014) Group inequality. J Eur Econ Assoc 12:129–152

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Boyd R, Gintis H, Bowles S (2010) Coordinated punishment of defectors sustains cooperation and can proliferate when rare. Science 328:617–620

    CAS  ADS  MathSciNet  Article  Google Scholar 

  19. Boyd R, Richerson PJ (1992) Punishment allows the evolution of cooperation (or anything else) in sizable groups. Ethol Sociobiol 13:171–195. https://doi.org/10.1016/0162-3095(92)90032-Y

    Article  Google Scholar 

  20. Brosnan Sarah F, Bshary R (2016) On potential links between inequity aversion and the structure of interactions for the evolution of cooperation. Behaviour 153:1267–1292. https://doi.org/10.1163/1568539X-00003355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Burton-Chellew MN, May RM, West SA (2013) Combined inequality in wealth and risk leads to disaster in the climate change game. Climatic Change 120:815–830. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10584-013-0856-7

    ADS  Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Campennì M, Schino G (2014) Partner choice promotes cooperation: the two faces of testing with agent-based models. J Theor Biol 344:49–55. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jtbi.2013.11.019

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  23. Campennì M, Schino G (2016) Symmetry-based reciprocity: evolutionary constraints on a proximate mechanism. PeerJ 4:e1812. https://doi.org/10.7717/peerj.1812

    CAS  Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  24. Chapais B (2015) Competence and the evolutionary origins of status and power in humans. Hum Nat 26:161–183. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12110-015-9227-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Cherry TL, Kroll S, Shogren JF (2005) The impact of endowment heterogeneity and origin on public good contributions: evidence from the lab. J Econ Behav Organ 57: 357–365

  26. Clutton-Brock TH, Parker GA (1995) Punishment in animal societies. Nature 373:209–216

    CAS  ADS  Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Cohen MN (1998) The emergence of health and social inequalities in the archaeological record. In: Strickland SS, Prakash S (eds) Human biology and social inequality. Cambridge University Press, p. 249

  28. Cox JC, Ostrom E, Sadiraj V, Walker JM (2013) Provision versus appropriation in symmetric and asymmetric social dilemmas. South Econ J 79:496–512

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Cronin KA, Acheson DJ, Rojas P, Sánchez A (2015) Hierarchy is detrimental for human cooperation. Sci Rep 5:18634. https://doi.org/10.1038/srep18634

  30. Dal Bó P (2005) Cooperation under the shadow of the future: experimental evidence from infinitely repeated games. Am Econ Rev 25:1591–1604

    Google Scholar 

  31. David-Barrett T, Dunbar RIM (2012) Cooperation, behavioural synchrony and status in social networks. J Theor Biol 308:88–95

    MathSciNet  Article  Google Scholar 

  32. David-Barrett T, Dunbar RIM (2013) Social elites can emerge naturally when interaction in networks is restricted. Behav Ecol 25:58–68. https://doi.org/10.1093/beheco/art085

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Dong Y, Sasaki T, Zhang B (2019) The competitive advantage of institutional reward. Proc R Soc B 286(1899):20190001. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2019.0001

  34. Dreber A, Rand DG, Fudenberg D, Nowak MA (2008) Winners don’t punish. Nature 452:348–351

    CAS  ADS  Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Fehr E, Gachter S (2002) Altruistic punishment in humans. Nature 415:137–140. https://doi.org/10.1038/415137a

    CAS  ADS  Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  36. Fehr E, Schurtenberger I (2018) Normative foundations of human cooperation. Nat Hum Behav 2:458–468. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41562-018-0385-5

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  37. Fischbacher U (2007) z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Exp Econ 10:171–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Fix B (2019) Energy, hierarchy and the origin of inequality. PLoS ONE 14:e0215692. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0215692

  39. Fowler JH, Johnson T, Smirnov O (2005) Egalitarian motive and altruistic punishment. Nature 433:E1. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature03256

  40. Frank SA (1996) Policing and group cohesion when resources vary. Anim Behav 52:1163–1169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  41. Frank SA (2010) A general model of the public goods dilemma. J Evol Biol 23:1245–1250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Gächter S, Mengel F, Tsakas E, Vostroknutov A (2017) Growth and inequality in public good provision. J Public Econ 150:1–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  43. Gächter S, Renner E, Sefton M (2008) The long-lun benefits of punishment. Science 322:1510. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1164744

  44. Gao L, Wang Z, Pansini R, Li Y-T, Wang R-W (2015) Collective punishment is more effective than collective reward for promoting cooperation. Sci Rep 5:17752. https://doi.org/10.1038/srep17752

    CAS  ADS  Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  45. Gavrilets S, Fortunato L (2014) A solution to the collective action problem in between-group conflict with within-group inequality. Nat Commun 5. https://doi.org/10.1038/ncomms4526

  46. Greif A, Tabellini G (2010) Cultural and institutional bifurcation: China and Europe compared. Am Econ Rev 100:135–140. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.2.135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  47. Hauser OP, Kraft-Todd GT, Rand DG, Nowak MA, Norton MI (2019) Invisible inequality leads to punishing the poor and rewarding the rich. Behav Public Policy 1–21. https://doi.org/10.1017/bpp.2019.4

  48. Henrich J, Boyd R (2008) Division of labor, economic specialization, and the evolution of social stratification. Curr Anthropol 49:715–724

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. Herbst L, Konrad KA, Morath F (2017) Balance of power and the propensity of conflict. Games Econ Behav 103:168–184. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2015.12.013

    MathSciNet  Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  50. Herrmann E, Haux LM, Zeidler H, Engelmann JM (2019) Human children but not chimpanzees make irrational decisions driven by social comparison. Proc R Soc B 286:20182228. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2018.2228

  51. Hilbe C, Traulsen A, Röhl T, Milinski M (2014) Democratic decisions establish stable authorities that overcome the paradox of second-order punishment. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 111:752–756. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1315273111

  52. Holland J, Silva AS, Mace R (2012) Lost letter measure of variation in altruistic behaviour in 20 neighbourhoods. PLoS ONE 7:e43294–e43294

    CAS  ADS  Article  Google Scholar 

  53. Horváth R (2013) Does trust promote growth? J Comp Econ 41:777–788. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2012.10.006

    Article  Google Scholar 

  54. Hume D (1975) A treatise of human nature. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  55. Inglehart RF, Basanez M, Basanez M, Moreno A (1998) Human values and beliefs: a cross-cultural sourcebook. University of Michigan Press

  56. Inkpen AC, Beamish PW (1997) Knowledge, bargaining power, and the instability of international joint ventures. J Acad Manag Rev 22:177–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  57. Jacobs M, Mazzucato M (2016) Rethinking capitalism: economics and policy for sustainable and inclusive growth. John Wiley & Sons

  58. Janssen MA, Bushman C (2008) Evolution of cooperation and altruistic punishment when retaliation is possible. J Theor Biol 254:541–545

    MathSciNet  Article  Google Scholar 

  59. Jizhe N (2016) China statistical yearbook 2016. CS Press

  60. Joyce R, Xu X (2019) Inequalities in the twenty-first century: introducing the IFS Deaton Review. The Institute for Fiscal Studies

  61. Jusup M, Wang Z, Shi L, Lee J-H, Iwasa Y, Boccaletti S (2018) Exploiting a cognitive bias promotes cooperation in social dilemma experiments. Nat Commun 9:2954

    ADS  Article  Google Scholar 

  62. Keltner D, Gruenfeld DH, Anderson C (2003) Power, approach, and inhibition. Psychol Rev 110:265–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  63. Kets W, Iyengar G, Sethi R, Bowles S (2011) Inequality and network structure. Games Econ Behav 73:215–226

    MathSciNet  Article  Google Scholar 

  64. Kuwabara K, Yu S, Lee AJ, Galinsky AD (2016) Status decreases dominance in the west but increases dominance in the east. Psychol Sci 27:127–137. https://doi.org/10.1177/0956797615612694

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  65. Kuznetsova A, Brockhoff PB, Christensen RHB (2015) Package ‘lmerTest’. R package version: 2.0-29

  66. Landtman G (1934) The origin of the inequality of the social classes. Routledge

  67. Lee RB (1990) Primitive communism and the origin of social inequality. In: Upham S (ed) Evolution of political systems: sociopolitics in small-scale sedentary societies. Cambridge University Press, pp. 225–246

  68. Li X, Jusup M, Wang Z, Li H, Shi L, Podobnik B, Stanley HE, Havlin S, Boccaletti S (2018) Punishment diminishes the benefits of network reciprocity in social dilemma experiments. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 115:30–35. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1707505115

  69. Lockett H (2016) China anti-corruption campaign backfires. Financial Times. https://www.ft.com/content/02f712b4-8ab8-11e6-8aa5-f79f5696c731

  70. Mattison SM, Smith EA, Shenk MK, Cochrane EE (2016) The evolution of inequality. Evol Anthropol 25:184–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  71. Nikiforakis N (2008) Punishment and counter-punishment in public good games: can we really govern ourselves? J Public Econ 92:91–112. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.04.008

    Article  Google Scholar 

  72. Nikiforakis N, Normann H-T, Wallace B (2010) Asymmetric enforcement of cooperation in a social dilemma. South Econ J 76:638–659. https://doi.org/10.4284/sej.2010.76.3.638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  73. O’Gorman R, Henrich J, Van Vugt M (2009) Constraining free riding in public goods games: designated solitary punishers can sustain human cooperation. Proc R Soc B 276: 323–329

  74. Pansini R (2011) Induced cooperation to access a shareable reward increases the hierarchical segregation of wild vervet monkeys. PLoS ONE 6:e21993. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0021993

    CAS  ADS  Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  75. Pansini R (2012) Hierarchical societies of primates: comments on love, war and cultures. J Bioecon 15:97–101. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10818-012-9138-0

    Article  Google Scholar 

  76. Pansini R, Shi L, Wang R-W (2016) Women tend to defect in a social dilemma game in Southwest China. PLoS ONE 11:e0166101. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0166101

    CAS  Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  77. Phillips T (2017) The concepts of asymmetric and symmetric power can help resolve the puzzle of altruistic and cooperative behaviour. Biol Rev 93:457–468. https://doi.org/10.1111/brv.12352

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  78. Piff PK (2014) Wealth and the inflated self: class, entitlement, and narcissism. Pers Soc Psychol Bull 40:34–43. https://doi.org/10.1177/0146167213501699

    Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  79. Piff PK, Kraus MW, Cote S, Cheng BH, Keltner D (2010) Having less, giving more: the influence of social class on prosocial behavior. J Pers Soc Psychol 99:771–784. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0020092

    Article  Google Scholar 

  80. Piff PK, Stancato DM, Côté S, Mendoza-Denton R, Keltner D (2012) Higher social class predicts increased unethical behavior. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 109: 4086–4091

  81. R Core Team (2016) R: A language and environment for statistical computing. R Foundation for Statistical Computing, R Core Team, Vienna, Austria

    Google Scholar 

  82. Raihani NJ, Bshary R (2015) Third-party punishers are rewarded, but third-party helpers even more so. Evolution 69:993–1003. https://doi.org/10.1111/evo.12637

    Article  Google Scholar 

  83. Raihani NJ, Thornton A, Bshary R (2012) Punishment and cooperation in nature. Trends Ecol Evol 27:288–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  84. Rankin DJ, dos Santos M, Wedekind C (2009) The evolutionary significance of costly punishment is still to be demonstrated. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 106: E135. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0911990107

  85. Reuben E, Riedl A (2013) Enforcement of contribution norms in public good games with heterogeneous populations. Games Econ Behav 77:122–137

    MathSciNet  Article  Google Scholar 

  86. Riehl C, Frederickson ME (2016) Cheating and punishment in cooperative animal societies. Phil. Trans. R. Soc. B 371:20150090. https://doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2015.0090

  87. Scheffer M, van Bavel B, van de Leemput IA, van Nes EH (2017) Inequality in nature and society. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 114:13154–13157. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1706412114

  88. Smith EA, Choi J-K (2007) The emergence of inequality in small-scale societies: simple scenarios and agent-based simulations. The model-based archaeology of socionatural systems. SAR Press, pp. 105–120

  89. Steckermeier LC, Delhey J (2018) Better for everyone? Egalitarian culture and social wellbeing in Europe. Social Indicators Research 143:1075–1108. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11205-018-2007-z

  90. Suchak M, Eppley TM, Campbell MW, Feldman RA, Quarles LF, de Waal FBM (2016) How chimpanzees cooperate in a competitive world. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 113:10215–10220. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1611826113

  91. The Economist (2012) Gini out of the bottle. http://www.economist.com/news/china/21570749-gini-out-bottle

  92. Triandis HC (1995) Individualism & collectivism. Westview Press, Boulder

    Google Scholar 

  93. Uslaner EM (2005) Inequality, trust, and civic engagement. Am Politics Res 33:868–884. https://doi.org/10.1177/1532673X04271903

    Article  Google Scholar 

  94. van Vugt M, Tybur JM (2015) The evolutionary foundations of status hierarchy. The handbook of evolutionary psychology. John Wiley & Sons, Inc., pp. 788–809

  95. Vanberg VJ, Congleton RD (1992) Rationality, morality, and exit. Am Political Sci Rev 86:418–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  96. Vincent A (2017) Punishment and status in collective action: how status hierarchies foster optimal punishment use. Sociol Compass 11:e12478. https://doi.org/10.1111/soc4.12478

  97. Wang R-W, He J, Wang Y, Shi L, Li Y (2010) Asymmetric interaction will facilitate the evolution of cooperation. Sci China Life Sci 53:1041–1046. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11427-010-4016-2

  98. Wang Z, Kokubo S, Jusup M, Tanimoto J (2015) Universal scaling for the dilemma strength in evolutionary games. Phys Life Rev 14:1–30. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.plrev.2015.04.033

    ADS  Article  Google Scholar 

  99. West SA, Griffin AS, Gardner A (2007) Evolutionary explanations for cooperation. Curr Biol 17:R661–R672

    CAS  Article  Google Scholar 

  100. Whiteside MD, Werner GDA, Caldas VEA, van’t Padje A, Dupin SE, Elbers B, Bakker M, Wyatt GAK, Klein M, Hink MA, Postma M, Vaitla B, Noë R, Shimizu TS, West SA, Kiers ET (2019) Mycorrhizal fungi respond to resource inequality by moving phosphorus from rich to poor patches across networks. Curr Biol. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cub.2019.04.061

  101. Wike R, Stokes B (2016) Chinese public sees more powerful role in world, names U.S. as top threat. Domestic challenges persist: corruption, consumer safety, pollution. In: Numbers, facts and trends shaping the world. Pew Research Center, p. 29

  102. Wilson DS, O’Brien DT, Sesma A (2009) Human prosociality from an evolutionary perspective: variation and correlations at a city-wide scale. Evol Hum Behav 30:190–200. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.evolhumbehav.2008.12.002

    Article  Google Scholar 

  103. Wu J-J, Zhang B-Y, Zhou Z-X, He Q-Q, Zheng X-D, Cressman R, Tao Y (2009) Costly punishment does not always increase cooperation. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 106:17448–17451. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0905918106

  104. Wubs M, Bshary R, Lehmann L (2016) Coevolution between positive reciprocity, punishment, and partner switching in repeated interactions. Proc R Soc B 283. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2016.0488

  105. Xia C-Y, Meng X-K, Wang Z (2015) Heterogeneous coupling between interdependent lattices promotes the cooperation in the prisoner’s dilemma game. PLoS ONE 10:e0129542. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0129542

    CAS  Article  PubMed  PubMed Central  Google Scholar 

  106. Xie W, Ho B, Meier S, Zhou X (2017) Rank reversal aversion inhibits redistribution across societies. Nat Hum Behav 1:0142. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41562-017-0142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  107. Xie Y, Zhou X (2014) Income inequality in today’s China. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 111: 6928–6933. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1403158111

  108. Xin G (2017) Trust and economic performance: a panel study. Mpra Paper, 80815

  109. Yamagishi T (1986) The provision of a sanctioning system as a public good. J Pers Soc Psychol 51:110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  110. Zeng W, Ai H, Zhao M (2019) Asymmetrical expectations of future interaction and cooperation in the iterated prisoner’s dilemma game. Appl Math Comput 359:148–164. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.amc.2019.04.067

    MathSciNet  Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  111. Zhang M, Ma Y, Tao Y, Wang Z, Shi L, Wang R-W (2020) Awareness of wealth inequalities breeds animosity. Chaos Solitons Fractals 130:109398. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chaos.2019.109398

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The master students of the Behavioral and Experimental Economics Research Center, Bo Ma and Zhi Peng Zhou, contributed to data collection. Chun-Lei Yang and Rui-Wu Wang commented on the experiment. Nicola Raihani commented on the draft. Jordyn Steig edited it for the English language. RP obtained funding from the Chinese Academy of Science President’s International Fellowship Initiative (grant number 2015PB058) and the National Natural Science Foundation of China (31450110421). MC thanks the John Templeton Foundation for funding The Human Generosity Project. L.S. was supported by a NNSFC key project (11931015) and another NNSFC project (11671348).

Author information

Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding authors

Correspondence to Riccardo Pansini or Lei Shi.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher’s note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Supplementary information

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this license, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Reprints and Permissions

About this article

Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Pansini, R., Campennì, M. & Shi, L. Segregating socioeconomic classes leads to an unequal redistribution of wealth. Palgrave Commun 6, 46 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41599-020-0419-2

Download citation

Further reading

Search

Quick links