Introduction

Networks have always played a special role for human beings in shaping social relations, forming public opinion, and driving economic equilibria. Trade history since barter has been based on networks of producers, consumers, and intermediaries; the banking sector has developed since the Renaissance on the basis of networks, the currency has emerged as a medium of exchange recognized by networks of individuals, and the entire financial sector has evolved through the development of investor networks.

More recently, the rise and consolidation of the Internet as an enabling infrastructure has dramatically transformed the ecosystem and its dynamics. The Internet, which is a network of networks, has promoted the creation of comprehensive global connections. Trade has turned into a global network run by intermediaries who leverage the power of networks (of users and producers)1, finance is based on the matching of networks resulting in very volatile reactions2, and (crypto)currencies emerge according to a “spontaneous” process driven by network effects3. It is no coincidence that social relations in the last twenty years have been shaped within a digital sphere dominated by networked platforms4,5.

Unprecedented in the history of capitalism, online networked platforms have in just a few years achieved dominant positions in many digital and traditional markets and have quickly dominated capitalization leaderboards6. At the end of 2021, the top four companies in the world by market capitalisation were networked platforms (i.e., Apple, Microsoft, Alphabet, and Amazon), which were 6 out of the top 10 (the above four plus Meta and Tencent).

To understand this evolution, therefore, we must understand networks, how they are organised, how they evolve, and what laws they follow. The aim of the article is to examine the dynamic laws that new networked platforms follow also in relation to the laws of legacy technologies (broadcasting, peer-to-peer communication, etc.).

Analysing networks

From a general point of view, the concept of network extends to all those structures in which the economic (and social) relations of agents are mutually interdependent (so that “coordination” issues occur). In the classical case, the utility of a service (e.g. a telephone service, a messenger service or a social network) for a consumer depends on the number of users who have already joined the network. This effect is referred to as “direct network externalities”. Since platforms are intermediaries linking two (or more) types of agents (e.g. users and advertisers, users and shopkeepers) and thus operate on two- (or more) sided markets these relationships may be indirect. This kind of effects is referred to as “indirect (or cross-side) network externalities”. For instance, a search engine exploits the inter-dependency between users and advertisers, by clustering groups and subgroups of users and reselling them on the advertising side (as well as providing customised services); it thus creates and connects networks of agents from seemingly separate domains. In this respect, networks include broadcasting networks (in which a central node transmits a message to peripheral nodes), telephone networks (in which users are linked by peer-to-peer relations), search engines (in which a platform links two or more networks of distinct agents potentially clustered within groups) and, of course, social networks (in which users create group and sub-group relations).

Notice that such a concept of network is different from what is normally intended in scientific fields like network science7: in fact, in economics network effects are the phenomena by which the value depends on the number of users without assuming a knowledge of the network topology.

Indeed, networks can be analysed from several aspects. Network analysis investigates the topology of networks, examining their nodes and links, their relation (the density, i.e., the ratio of links to nodes), the directionality of links (either directed or undirected), as well as the formation of clusters. Recent literature on the structure of social relationships within social networks has shown the formation of clusters based on homophily, with little mutual communication between different groups (so-called polarisation)8.

The analysis of network topology is fascinating and fundamental to understanding the phenomenon, but it clashes with two major challenges. First, most networks that govern economic and social life (social networks, search engines, e-commerce networks, online trading platforms, etc.) are private. It is therefore challenging (for reasons ranging from trade secrecy to privacy issues) to acquire enough information to conduct a comprehensive network topology analysis. Consequently, it is often unfeasible to define general metrics that describe network topologies  comprehensively and concisely (i.e., what statisticians refer to as sufficient statistics9) and can be calculated consistently over time.

Given the economic and financial prominencey of networked platforms in contemporary economies and societies, some metrics have nevertheless been defined. These metrics are primarily based on a single piece of information: the number of participants in the networks. Traditional networks (e.g., TV and radio broadcasting networks) have been evaluated on the basis of contacts reached (e.g., in terms of audience share). More recently, telecommunications companies have been investigated on the basis of the number of users forming their networks (e.g., in terms of mobile SIM cards). Lastly, networked platforms such as social networks are evaluated based on the number of network participants.

The use of the number of participants to characterise a network has become standard also for reasons concerning economic theory. Since the 1970s10, economic models describing the behaviour of networked markets have included the size of the network within the utility functions of the users. In the presence of (direct and indirect) network effects, as the number of network participants rises, the utility of users increases accordingly, thus producing positive feedback loops and “the winner takes all” market dynamics6,11.

The presence of non-linearities may thus translate into the value of networks. In particular, this article aims to test the following hypotheses that appear particularly important for understanding the role that networked platforms have acquired in modern economies and societies:

H1::

the value of new networked platforms follows dynamics (power-law or exponential) that are faster than those of previous technologies (linear or quadratic).

H2::

the network value dynamics is dependent of the geographical and market context.

H3::

the dynamics of the network’s financial value is linked to that of its economic value.

From now on, unless otherwise specified, we will use the term “value” as “economic value”, i.e. the annual revenues generated by a network (e.g. advertising revenues from brands to reach network’s users). Instead, for “financial value” we will intend the average stock market value of the network company (only for companies whose value depends almost exclusively on the network) in the same reference year.

Testing the dynamics of the value of networks

Over the years, the relationship between network size and network value has been the subject of numerous “laws” that have been proposed by researchers and practitioners. Although these network laws influence important decisions (such as the financial evaluation of companies and related investment decisions), they are neither based on sound theoretical foundations nor on empirical evidence.

These laws associate the value of the network not only with the number of participants but also with the type of technology. In other words, while the value of the network always depends on the number of participants, its dynamics is related to the generation of the communication technology.

The value of a broadcasting network (i.e. where a single node communicates unidirectionally to all the others) increases proportionally to the number of users: this relationship is referred to as “Sarnoff’s law”12 by David Sarnoff, a titan of the radio and TV broadcast era, who led the Radio Corporation of America (which created NBC) from 1919 until 1970. In Metcalfe’s law13 instead, the value of communications networks grows in proportion to the number of possible links among couples of users, i.e. to the square of the number of users on the network. Robert Metcalfe, who was one of the inventors of the Ethernet standard, proposed this law in the 1980s to describe p2p communication networks like fax or phone networks. Finally, in 1999, David Reed14, from MIT, proposed, for group-forming networks like instant messaging, that the value of the network increases as \(2^N\) (where N is the number of participants) since this is the number of all possible subgroups that can be formed in a network consisting of N nodes.

Consequently, the relationship we observe between network value (V) and the number of participants (N) provides insights into the type of connections that characterise the network. Sarnoff’s and Metcalfe’s laws have been empirically generalised by Nivi as:

$$\begin{aligned} V \propto N^\gamma . \end{aligned}$$

Sarnoff’s law corresponds to \(\gamma = 1\), Metcalfe’s to \(\gamma = 2\), while \(\gamma > 2\) allows accounting for faster power-law growths. Interestingly, Nivi’s law15 can also be justified theoretically with some hypotheses on the way groups form (see “Methods”).

The exponent \(\gamma\) provides information on the linearity/non-linearity of network value growth with respect to the number of participants. In other words, the estimated value of \(\gamma\) indicates whether the value of networked platforms follows a linear dynamic such as that of broadcasting (i.e., \(\gamma = 1\)), a quadratic pattern as that of peer-to-peer networks (\(\gamma = 2\)), or a more explosive path (\(\gamma > 2\)).

Reed’s law has never been observed in real networks’ data since it can be considered an upper bound to the network value. So, it is possible to generalise Reed’s law (see S2) to the case of an exponential growth “slower” than the \(2^N\) case:

$$\begin{aligned} V \propto e^{\rho N}, \end{aligned}$$

corresponding to selecting only a fraction of all possible subgroups. In this case, \(\rho\) is the network value’s growth rate bounded by the maximum value \(\rho = \ln 2\) (i.e., 0.69) corresponding to the original Reed’s law.

In the following, we will compare Nivi’s growth \(V \propto N^\gamma\) to the nested model \(V \propto N^2\) corresponding to Metcalfe’s growth via the likelihood of the corresponding regressions16 . We will then use the information-theoretic approach to model selection17to verify whether the value dynamics of networked platforms follows an exponential (Reed) or power law (Nivi) pattern.

The value of advertising-funded networks

Among the most important networks are those funded by advertising. Commercial TVs and radio broadcasters, search engines, video sharing platforms, and social networks are two-sided networks that offer free services on the one side (the user side) and make money from selling advertising to advertisers on the other.

Traditional media networks sell aggregate and undifferentiated contacts. In this case, the value of these networks is related to the number of people who come in contact with the network and thus follows a linear pattern (Sarnoff’s law). Online networks, on the other hand, have the ability to sell subgroups (so-called targets) categorised on the basis of specific characteristics (e.g., age, gender, ethnicity, income, location). This results in network values that grow non-linearly with respect to the value of the users (Nivi and/or Reed’s laws). It should be noted that while network effects can benefit (also) users by creating a reinforcement feedback loop that increases the intrinsic non-monetary value of the network and thus expands its user size (so-called bandwagon effect), the non-linearity of the economic value depends on the ability to sell information about users to advertisers and to create different targets and subgroups. In other words, the benefits from network externalities are monetized on the advertising side.

Networked platforms versus legacy technologies

To verify the dynamics of the value of ad-networks with potentially unlimited connections among participants, we first focus on the US market, where we analyse search engines (i.e., Google), video streaming platforms (i.e., YouTube), and social networking (i.e., Facebook, Instagram, Reddit, Twitter, LinkedIn, Pinterest and Snapchat) over a period of 20 years (i.e. 2002–2021). This choice is consistent with market analysis: “The United States is a relevant geographic market for personal social networking services due to several factors . . . network effects between users are generally stronger between users in the same country, because for most users the vast majority of relevant friends, family, and other personal connections reside in the same country as the user. Accordingly, users in the United States predominantly share content with other users in the United States” (Federal Trade Commission vs. Facebook Inc., Case No.: 1:20-cv-03590-JEB, paragraph169, August 2021).

Table 1 Test for Nivi’s exponents.
Table 2 Akaike test for Reed’s and Nivi’s law.
Table 3 Predictive performance.

To test the dynamics of the network value, we calculate the parameter \(\gamma\) on which we perform a likelihood-ratio test16 (also known as Wilks test) respect to Metcalfe’s law corresponding to fixing \(\gamma = 2\). In Table 1, we show that the estimated \(\gamma\)’s are always significantly greater than 2 (note that the p values of the Wilks test are all \(<0.01\)), indicating that the value of networked platforms grows faster than the Metcalfe’s law (i.e., legacy technologies). In addition, the values of the coefficients of determination \(R^2\sim 1\) indicate a good accordance with data. Accordingly, we observe that Nivi’s model has a better predictive performance than Metcalfe’s (Table 3).

Model selection: power law versus exponential

Figure 1
figure 1

Network Value for online services in the US market. The advertising revenues for several US network companies grow faster than quadratically and are better fitted either by the generalised Reed’s law (exponential growth) or by Nivi’s law (power law growth), with exponents varying from \(\gamma \sim 3\) to \(\gamma \sim 14\) (see Table 1).

Figure 2
figure 2

Network Value for the geographical areas of META. The advertising revenues grow faster than quadratically and are better fitted either by the generalised Reed’s law (exponential growth) or by Nivi’s law (power law growth), with exponents varying from \(\gamma \sim 2.2\) to \(\gamma \sim 6\) (see Table 1).

In Figs. 1 and 2, we show the accordance of the data with the fits of Reed’s (exponential) and Nivi’s (power law) models both for multiple platforms in the US market and for the different geographic market areas (of Meta, i.e., Facebook + Instagram). Neither visual inspection nor the \(R^2\) values (see also SI) allow to select a better model. Since Reed’s and Nivi’s laws cannot be defined as nested statistical models, standard log-likelihood ratio test cannot be applied17. Thus, we have employed the information-theoretic approach to model selection17 to discriminate among the two models (see also SI). As shown in Table 2, the data are not conclusive (apart in the case of META’s aggregated World data) in discriminating whether Reed’s or Nivi’s is the best model, indicating some heterogeneity linked to the geographical context (it generally follows an exponential pattern in the US, and a power law elsewhere). Accordingly, we observe that—apart for META’s aggregated World data, the predictive performance of both models are comparable (see Table 3).

Finally, it should be noted that, as expected (see “Methods”), \(\rho\) is always significantly less than 0.69 (see above), displaying predictable variability depending on services (it is greater in social networks than in search engines and video sharing), and geographical context (it is greater in national markets than in transnational areas such as the World or Other countries).

Determinants of value network dynamics

To check for heterogeneity in the network growth across different geographical areas, we investigate the data for the global platform Meta (see Fig. 2). A shown in Table 1, we observe again that: (1) the estimated \(\gamma\)’s are significantly greater than 2; (2) there is a good accordance with data as indicated by the values of the coefficients of determination \(R^2\sim 1\); (3) we observe a strong correlation of \(\gamma\) with the per-capita income of different countries (\(R^2 = 0.79\), see Fig. 4), hinting that \(\gamma\) summarises the platform’s ability to economically leverage its network of users. A possible explanation of such effect is that where per-capita income is higher, users’ willingness to pay for consumer goods and services is higher, thus increasing the opportunity to economically exploit, through the sale of advertising, the network.

Note also that the value of \(\gamma\) is highest in the case of dominant platforms in each service (Google for search engines, Facebook for social networking and YouTube for video sharing platforms). With specific reference to social networks, it should be also noted that the values of \(\gamma\) for LinkedIn and Reddit is lower probably because both networks rely, in addition to advertising, on premium membership revenues.

Economic and financial value

To investigate the relation between the network value and is financial value using as a measure its market capitalization, we analyse publicly traded network companies for the World market; i.e. a search engine (Google) and four social networking platforms (Meta, Twitter, Pinterest and Snapchat). It should be noted that the financial value reflects the market’s expected value of the present and future discounted profits of the networked platform.

Figure 3
figure 3

Market capitalization over Network value ratio. The yearly behaviour of the multiplier \(\mu\), corresponding to the ratio between the market capitalization and the total return on advertising, shows convergence to a plateau around \(\mu \sim 10\) (but for Snapchat—which however is converging to the plateau in 2022).

Figure 4
figure 4

Meta data: relation between Nivi’s exponent \(\gamma\) and GDP per capita (in thousands of USD) in different geographical areas.

To capture the relation among the network economic value V and the financial value F, we study the ratio \(\mu =F/V\) among the two; such ratio is a multiplier of the economic value of the network. A constant ratio over time would indicate that the market prizes the company according to its sales. In Fig. 3, we show the time evolution of the ratio \(\mu\) among market capitalization and advertising revenues. We notice that for Google, Meta and Twitter such multiplier stabilises around \(\mu \sim 10\); a similar value is attained by considering also Pinterest data. On the other hand, Snapchat data are anomalous in such regard: in fact, after reaching a value \(\mu \sim 10\) from 2017 to 2019, it grows up to an anomalous value thrice larger in 2021. However, it should be noted that in accordance with our observations, Snapchat’s market value dropped significantly in 2022, such that it fell between January and June by nearly 70%, yielding an estimated multiplier \(\mu \sim 9\) consistent with the plateau values of Fig. 3.

In sum, data seem to show that in the medium term \(F = \mu V\) along all platforms, indicating that the financial market prizes these companies proportionally to their economic network value, so that in equilibrium (regardless of speculative perturbations) also the financial value follows “explosive” growth laws.

Discussion

Economies and societies are based on networks of agents and citizens, and their governance has dramatically changed in recent decades with the establishment of the Internet as an enabling infrastructure and the resulting shift in socio-economic dynamics toward nonlinear patterns. Yet surprisingly, knowledge of these dynamics is still scarce and based on scientifically unsound “laws” and scant empirical evidence.

Here we developed a comprehensive model and tested the dynamics of the (economic and financial) value of online ad-funded networks. The results show a strongly nonlinear trend, especially when focusing on a specific geographical area. In particular we have found that:

  • the economic value of networked platforms (i.e., search engines, social networks, and video sharing platforms) follows a dynamic that is faster than that characterizing previous generation technologies (linear, i.e., Sarnoff law, for broadcasting, and quadratic, Metcalfe law, for peer-to-peer networks);

  • the estimated models are in most cases not conclusive with respect to the type of nonlinear dynamics (i.e., whether power law or exponential); however, they show heterogeneity depending on the type of service and the geographical context;

  • in this regard, the dynamics appear to depend on factors such as the market power gained by the networked platform and the average willingness to pay of local users;

  • finally, the financial value of networked platforms, and its dynamics, is intertwined, at least in the medium term, with the economic value. Put another way, the explosive dynamic found at the economic level appears to reverberate on the value that financial markets assign to these platforms.

Despite the economic and social importance of the phenomena analysed, to the authors’ knowledge, this is the first analysis to investigate the dynamics just described. This article is therefore a first step that foreshadows a variety of interesting future research developments. First, the availability of more granular data—at network, geographical and time levels—would give the possibility of more observations and thus even more comprehensive results. In fact, while out tests indicate that network platforms grow faster than legacy technologies, the present evidence is not enough to discriminate among Nivi’s or generalised Reed. Second, by gathering historical data on legacy technologies (broadcasting networks, peer-to-peer networks), different dynamical patterns could be compared in a robust way. Third, public or otherwise available data that would allow to estimate topological network statistics (like data on the links among the users) would clarify further aspects of the analysed dynamics that go beyond economic concepts related to economic network effects. Finally, having analysed a period of strong expansion of digital services, the non linearity of the dynamics has resulted in explosive growth. However, this dynamics can also apply in the opposite direction.

Methods

Data sources

Data on users and advertising revenues are, where available, from eMarketer. Data can be requested via access to the Insider Intelligence database. These data cover both the US and global markets (and for Meta also Canada, France, Germany, Italy Spain, and UK). For the early years of operation of “older” networked platforms (before 2008) these data are often not available. In that case, they have been supplemented by other sources such as companies’ financial statements (e.g., Google, Alphabet), other official communications to the financial community (e.g. IPOs), and Statista. Data on Google users are elaborations from comScore data. Data on countries’ GDP per-capita are from the World Bank and pertain to the year 2021. Finally, data on the market capitalization of companies are average annual values computed from daily data from Bloomberg (as of the day of IPO).

Data analysis

To determine which law fits better our data on the network values, we apply non-linear least square minimization of the following functional forms

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{ll} V = a_M N^2 &{} \text {Metcalfe} \\ V = a_N N^\gamma &{} \text {Nivi}\\ V = a_R e^{\rho N} &{} \text {Reed} \end{array} \end{aligned}$$

that capture the scaling of network values respectively for Metcalfe’s, Nivi’s and generalised Reed’s law.

Since Metcalfe can be seen as a nested model of Nivi (its parameter are a subset of Nivi’s since Metcalfe can be obtained by setting \(\gamma =2\)), log-likelihood ratio tests16 allow to perform model selection among the twos along the different datasets. On the other hand, since Reed’s and Nivi’s laws cannot be defined as nested statistical models, we have applied the information-theoretic approach to model selection17 to discriminate among the two models along the different datasets by confronting Akaike’s \(\Delta\)’s (see also SI).

To test model’s predictive performance, we first calculate via a leave-one-out procedure the mean squared prediction error (MSPE)18. To compare models, we look at the ratio of the MSEs respect to the one for Metcalfe’s (see Table 3); if a model performs better than Metcalfe’s, its ratio will be \(<1\), while the ratio will be \(>1\) for worse prediction performing models. As expected, Nivi’s and Reed’s model show significantly lower MSPE ratios but for the cases of META’s data for World and Other countries, which both have an exponent \(\gamma \sim 2\). Further details can be found in the SI.

In the following, we derive the generalised Reed’s law under the minimal assumption that new users contribute to the formation of new groups at a reduced rate with respect to the original Reed’s law. We then derive the empirical Nivi’s law under the assumption that the rate of new groups’ formation is decreasing with the number of users.

Derivation of the network value’s growth laws

The advertising value of a network is related to the possibility of selling groups of users for targeted advertising; however, Reed’s intuition that network value should be linked to the number \(2^N\) of all possible subgroups has been criticised for having a too sharp increase of the network value19 never comforted by observational data20. Moreover, Reed’s Law cannot be economically correct: predicting that a network of 1010 users would have a value \(2^{10} \sim 1000\) larger than a network of 1000 users clashes with our expectations (and experience) about network values. It is in fact unrealistic to expect that each of the possible \(2^N\) groups can be sold to a different advertiser. Is it possible to adapt Reed’s core insight that there is value in group formation without violating common sense and economic data?

To develop simple models that restrict the possible groups to the “marketable” ones (i.e. the ones that can be sold), let’s observe that the number \(\Omega (n)\) of “marketable” subgroups of n users grows as \(\Omega (n+1) = \Omega (n) + \Delta \Omega (n)\) where \(\Delta \Omega (n)\) is the number of new groups that can be formed by adding a new user. In the original Reed’s approach, each new user allows creating of \(\Omega (n)\) new groups, leading to \(2^N\) groups for N users. However, in a real market, not all the new groups are saleable; thus we can suppose that a new individual has only a probability \(\rho\) of determining a new “marketable” group from an old one, i.e. \(\Delta \Omega (n) = \rho \Omega (n)\). Lets notice that, as soon as \(n>> 1\), it is convenient to express the growth in differential form, i.e. \(\partial _n \Omega (n) = \Delta \Omega (n)\); the solution of such a growth

$$\begin{aligned} \partial _n \Omega (n) = \rho \Omega (n) \end{aligned}$$

recovers exactly what we have called the generalised Reed’s growth

$$\begin{aligned} \Omega (n) \propto e^{\rho n} . \end{aligned}$$

The observed estimated values of \(\rho\) are extremely small (\(\sim 10^{-9}\), see Table 2 and S1), indicating that the probability that a user determines a new group is extremely small.

On the other hand, it is reasonable to assume that while at the beginning of the network formation it is very easy to create new “marketable” groups, it should become increasingly difficult to find new “marketable” groups when n grows. Accordingly, we should expect a growth law \(\Delta \Omega (n) = p(n) \Omega (n)\) where the probability p(n) of creating new “marketable” groups is now decreasing with n. An instructive and solvable case is to assume a simple Zipf’s law \(p(n)\propto 1/n\); such a law was empirically found in quantitative bibliographic studies indicating that the probability of finding “new” or “interesting” papers decreases approximately like the inverse of the number of analysed papers. Thus, assuming \(p(n) = \gamma /n\), we have a growth law

$$\begin{aligned} \partial _n \Omega (n) = \frac{\gamma }{n} \Omega (n) \end{aligned}$$

whose solution

$$\begin{aligned} \Omega (n) \propto n^\gamma \end{aligned}$$

recovers the empirical Nivi’s law.