Skip to main content

Thank you for visiting nature.com. You are using a browser version with limited support for CSS. To obtain the best experience, we recommend you use a more up to date browser (or turn off compatibility mode in Internet Explorer). In the meantime, to ensure continued support, we are displaying the site without styles and JavaScript.

  • Article
  • Published:

Sustainable natural resource governance under interest group competition in policy-making

Abstract

Non-state actors play an increasingly important role in environmental policy. Lobbying by interest groups has been associated with policy stagnation and environmental degradation as well as with sustainable governance. However, little is known about how competition between economic and environmental interests influences the ability of governance systems to avoid undesirable outcomes. We investigate how competing interest group behaviour affects sustainable resource management by tracing the policy change process in a case study of the European Union fisheries policy and analysing its dynamics with an agent-based model. We find that formation of interest group coalitions in response to a perceived crisis can delay or prevent collapses, even when the competing interests have unequal resources. We attribute such outcomes to the emergence and timing of a ‘tug of war’ mechanism between competing interest group coalitions. We argue that attempts to improve sustainable resource management must account for feedbacks from environmental change to behaviours of political actors.

This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution

Access options

Buy this article

Prices may be subject to local taxes which are calculated during checkout

Fig. 1: Overview of the processes in the PoliSEA model.

Icons designed by Jerker Lokrantz/Azote

Fig. 2: Results of experiment 1, exploring the effects of IGs’ coalition-building strategy on outcomes of the simulation.
Fig. 3: Dynamics of fish population in 200 model runs over time, under conditions of IGs’ coalition formation.
Fig. 4: Representative run for the fast decline scenario.
Fig. 5: Representative run for the slow decline scenario.
Fig. 6: Representative run for the balancing scenario.
Fig. 7: Results of experiment 2, exploring the role of IG funding in the performance of the fishery under conditions of IG coalitions.

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

The experiment output data that support the findings of this study are available from the corresponding author upon request. ODD + D protocol model documentation is included in Supplementary Note 1.

Code availability

The NetLogo code for the PoliSEA model is available for download from the OpenABM library:

https://www.comses.net/codebases/14c54b41-7fd6-4165-a15f-f76eec53af78/releases/1.1.0/.

References

  1. Hanna, S. S. Strengthening governance of ocean fishery resources. Ecol. Econ. 31, 275–286 (1999).

    Google Scholar 

  2. Crona, B. I. et al. Masked, diluted and drowned out: how global seafood trade weakens signals from marine ecosystems. Fish Fish. 17, 1175–1182 (2016).

    Google Scholar 

  3. Gunderson, L. H. & Holling, C. S. Panarchy: Understanding Transformations in Human and Natural Systems (Island Press, 2002).

  4. Beyers, J., Eising, R. & Maloney, W. Researching interest group politics in Europe and elsewhere: much we study, little we know? West Eur. Polit. 31, 1103–1128 (2008).

    Google Scholar 

  5. Orach, K., Schlüter, M. & Österblom, H. Tracing a pathway to success: how competing interest groups influenced the 2013 EU Common Fisheries Policy reform. Environ. Sci. Policy 76, 90–102 (2017).

    Google Scholar 

  6. Österblom, H. & Sumaila, U. R. Toothfish crises, actor diversity and the emergence of compliance mechanisms in the Southern Ocean. Glob. Environ. Change 21, 972–982 (2011).

    Google Scholar 

  7. Raustiala, K. States, NGOs, and international environmental institutions. Int. Stud. Q. 41, 719–740 (1997).

    Google Scholar 

  8. Ingold, K. Network structures within policy processes: coalitions, power, and brokerage in Swiss climate policy. Policy Stud. J. 39, 435–459 (2011).

    Google Scholar 

  9. Folke, C., Hahn, T., Olsson, P. & Norberg, J. Adaptive governance of social-ecological systems. Annu. Rev. Environ. Resour. 30, 441–473 (2005).

    Google Scholar 

  10. Chaffin, B. C., Gosnell, H. & Cosens, B. A. A decade of adaptive governance scholarship: synthesis and future directions. Ecol. Soc. 19, 56 (2014).

  11. Karpouzoglou, T., Dewulf, A. & Clark, J. Advancing adaptive governance of social-ecological systems through theoretical multiplicity. Environ. Sci. Policy 57, 1–9 (2016).

    Google Scholar 

  12. Lemos, M. C. & Agrawal, A. Environmental governance. Annu. Rev. Environ. Resour. 31, 297–325 (2006).

    Google Scholar 

  13. Dür, A. Interest groups in the European Union: how powerful are they? West Eur. Polit. 31, 1212–1230 (2008).

    Google Scholar 

  14. Mahoney, C. Brussels Versus the Beltway: Advocacy in the United States and the European Union (Georgetown Univ. Press, 2008).

  15. Hojnacki, M., Kimball, D. C., Baumgartner, F. R., Berry, J. M. & Leech, B. L. Studying organizational advocacy and influence: reexamining interest group research. Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. (Palo Alto) 15, 379–399 (2012).

    Google Scholar 

  16. Klüver, H. Lobbying in the European Union: Interest Groups, Lobbying Coalitions, and Policy Change (OUP, 2013).

  17. Voß, J.-P. & Bornemann, B. The politics of reflexive governance: challenges for designing adaptive management and transition management. Ecol. Soc. 16, 9 (2011).

    Google Scholar 

  18. Cote, M. & Nightingale, A. J. Resilience thinking meets social theory situating social change in socio-ecological systems (SES) research. Prog. Hum. Geogr. 36, 475–489 (2012).

    Google Scholar 

  19. Duit, A. Resilience thinking: lessons for public administration. Public Adm. 94, 364–380 (2015).

    Google Scholar 

  20. Sjöstedt, M. Resilience revisited: taking institutional theory seriously. Ecol. Soc. 20, 23 (2015).

    Google Scholar 

  21. Dahl, R. A. Who Governs? Democracy and Power in an American City (Yale Univ. Press, 1989).

  22. Lowery, D. & Gray, V. A neopluralist perspective on research on organized interests. Political Res. Q. 57, 164–175 (2004).

    Google Scholar 

  23. McFarland, A. S. Neopluralism. Annu. Rev. Politi. Sci. (Palo Alto) 10, 45–66 (2007).

    Google Scholar 

  24. Sabatier, P. A. Knowledge, policy-oriented learning, and policy change: an advocacy coalition framework. Sci. Commun. 8, 649–692 (1987).

    Google Scholar 

  25. Warleigh, A. The hustle: citizenship practice, NGOs and ‘policy coalitions’ in the European Union—the cases of Auto Oil, drinking water and unit pricing. J. Eur. Public Policy 7, 229–243 (2000).

    Google Scholar 

  26. Hojnacki, M. Interest groups’ decisions to join alliances or work alone. Am. J. Pol. Sci. 41, 61–87 (1997).

    Google Scholar 

  27. Mahoney, C. & Baumgartner, F. R. The determinants and effects of interest-group coalitions. In Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Chicago (2004).

  28. Bulkeley, H. & Mol, A. Participation and environmental governance: consensus, ambivalence and debate. Environ. Values 12, 143–154 (2003).

    Google Scholar 

  29. Dür, A. & De Bièvre, D. The question of interest group influence. J. Public Policy 27, 1–12 (2007).

    Google Scholar 

  30. Weible, C. M., Pattison, A. & Sabatier, P. A. Harnessing expert-based information for learning and the sustainable management of complex socio-ecological systems. Environ. Sci. Policy 13, 522–534 (2010).

    Google Scholar 

  31. Khalilian, S., Froese, R., Proelss, A. & Requate, T. Designed for failure: a critique of the Common Fisheries Policy of the European Union. Mar. Policy 34, 1178–1182 (2010).

    Google Scholar 

  32. Symes, D. The European Community’s Common Fisheries Policy. Ocean Coast. Manage. 35, 137–155 (1997).

    Google Scholar 

  33. Princen, S. Venue shifts and policy change in EU fisheries policy. Mar. Policy 34, 36–41 (2010).

    Google Scholar 

  34. Todd, E. & Ritchie, E. Environmental non-governmental organizations and the Common Fisheries Policy. Aquat. Conserv. 10, 141–149 (2000).

    Google Scholar 

  35. Junk, W. M. Co-operation as currency: how active coalitions affect lobbying success. J. Eur. Public Policy 0, 1–20 (2019).

    Google Scholar 

  36. Kingdon, J. W. Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Policies (Longman, 1995).

  37. Ostrom, E. Background on the institutional analysis and development framework. Policy Stud. J. 39, 7–27 (2011).

    Google Scholar 

  38. Thelen, K. Historical institutionalism in comparative politics. Annu. Rev. Political Sci. 2, 369–404 (1999).

    Google Scholar 

  39. Fisheries management. 2: The ecosystem approach to fisheries. (Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, 2003).

  40. Dür, A., Bernhagen, P. & Marshall, D. Interest group success in the European Union: when (and why) does business lose? Comp. Political Stud. 48, 951–983 (2015).

    Google Scholar 

  41. Zimmermann, H. The European Parliament and the layered politicization of the external dimension of the Common Fisheries Policy. Politics Gov. 7, 237 (2019).

    Google Scholar 

  42. Döring, R. & Egelkraut, T. M. Investing in natural capital as management strategy in fisheries: the case of the Baltic Sea cod fishery. Ecol. Econ. 64, 634–642 (2008).

    Google Scholar 

  43. Aps, R. & Lassen, H. Recovery of depleted Baltic Sea fish stocks: a review. ICES J. Mar. Sci. 67, 1856–1860 (2010).

    Google Scholar 

  44. Baumgartner, F. R. & Jones, B. D. in Policy Dynamics (eds Baumgartner, F. R. & Jones, B. D.) 3–28 (Univ. of Chicago Press, 2002).

  45. Biggs, R., Carpenter, S. R. & Brock, W. A. Turning back from the brink: detecting an impending regime shift in time to avert it. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 106, 826–831 (2009).

  46. Ley, A. J. Vested Interests, venue shopping, and policy stability: the long road to improving air quality in Oregon’s Willamette Valley. Rev. Policy Res. 33, 506–525 (2016).

    Google Scholar 

  47. Pierson, P. Not just what, but when: timing and sequence in political processes. Stud. Am. Political Dev. 14, 72–92 (2000).

    Google Scholar 

  48. Manson, S. M. & Evans, T. Agent-based modeling of deforestation in Southern Yucatán, Mexico, and reforestation in the Midwest United States. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 104, 20678–20683 (2007).

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  49. Lustick, I. S. & Miodownik, D. Abstractions, ensembles, and virtualizations simplicity and complexity in agent-based modeling. Comp. Polit. 41, 223–244 (2009).

    Google Scholar 

  50. Schlüter, M. et al. Capturing emergent phenomena in social-ecological systems—an analytical framework. Ecol. Soc. 24, https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-11012-240311 (2019).

  51. Maloney, W. A., Jordan, G. & McLaughlin, A. M. Interest groups and public policy: the insider/outsider model revisited. J. Public Policy 14, 17–38 (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  52. Hilborn, R. Managing fisheries is managing people: what has been learned? Fish Fish. 8, 285–296 (2007).

    Google Scholar 

  53. Klüver, H., Mahoney, C. & Opper, M. Framing in context: how interest groups employ framing to lobby the European Commission. J. Eur. Public Policy 22, 481–498 (2015).

    Google Scholar 

  54. Nohrstedt, D. & Weible, C. M. The logic of policy change after crisis: proximity and subsystem interaction. Risk Hazards Crisis Public Policy 1, 1–32 (2010).

    Google Scholar 

  55. Birkland, T. A. Focusing events, mobilization, and agenda setting. J. Public Policy 18, 53–74 (1998).

    Google Scholar 

  56. Hanegraaff, M. & Pritoni, A. United in fear: interest group coalition formation as a weapon of the weak? Eur. Union Polit. 20, 198–218 (2019).

    Google Scholar 

  57. Holyoke, T. T. Interest group competition and coalition formation. Am. J. Pol. Sci. 53, 360–375 (2009).

    Google Scholar 

  58. Heaney, M. T. & Lorenz, G. M. Coalition portfolios and interest group influence over the policy process. Interest Groups Advocacy 2, 251–277 (2013).

    Google Scholar 

  59. Mazey, S. & Richardson, J. Environmental groups and the EC: challenges and opportunities. Env. Polit. 1, 109–128 (1992).

    Google Scholar 

  60. Dür, A. & De Bièvre, D. Inclusion without Influence? NGOs in European trade policy. J. Public Policy 27, 79 (2007).

    Google Scholar 

  61. Lowery, D. Why do organized interests lobby? A multi-goal, multi-context theory of lobbying. Polity 39, 29–54 (2007).

    Google Scholar 

  62. Austen-Smith, D. & Wright, J. R. Counteractive lobbying. Am. J. Pol. Sci. 38, 25–44 (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  63. Rothenberg, L. S. Linking Citizens to Government: Interest Group Politics at Common Cause (Cambridge Univ. Press, 1992).

Download references

Acknowledgements

This research was made possible by the support of the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Seventh Framework Programme (FP/2007-2013/ERC grant agreement no. 283950 SES-LINK), the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme (ERC grant agreement no. 682472—MUSES; to K.O. and M.S.) and Marcus and Marianne Wallenberg Foundation (Grant no. 2017.0087 to A.D.). The funders had no role in study design, data collection and analysis, decision to publish or preparation of the manuscript. We would also like to thank E. Sundström for data analysis assistance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

K.O., A.D. and M.S. conceived the study and designed the experiments. K.O. led development and implementation of the model, conducted experiments and analysed the data with expertise and feedback from A.D. and M.S. K.O., M.S and A.D. wrote the manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kirill Orach.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Editor recognition statement Primary handling editor: Stavroula Kousta

Publisher’s note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Extended data

Extended Data Fig. 1 Interest group coalition-building decision.

Interest groups’ decision to join or form coalition(s) or lobby alone.

Extended Data Fig. 2 40/10 scenario of Experiment 2.

a, Fish population, b, quota, c, average number of interest coalitions and d, influence of lobbying groups during the 40/10 scenario. The dashed line in (a) and (b) represents the concern threshold of environmental (a) and industry (b) groups. The light blue field in (b) represents seasonal catch that can be taken out to maintain current fish population size (setting a quota above this value would lead to a decrease in the fish population next season).

Supplementary information

Supplementary Information

Supplementary tables and results.

Reporting Summary

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Orach, K., Duit, A. & Schlüter, M. Sustainable natural resource governance under interest group competition in policy-making. Nat Hum Behav 4, 898–909 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1038/s41562-020-0885-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1038/s41562-020-0885-y

Search

Quick links

Nature Briefing

Sign up for the Nature Briefing newsletter — what matters in science, free to your inbox daily.

Get the most important science stories of the day, free in your inbox. Sign up for Nature Briefing