Introduction

In the Paris Agreement, countries agreed to limit global warming to well below 2 °C, and preferably 1.5 °C1. For implementation, the Paris Agreement relies on mitigation action at the national level. These actions are communicated via nationally determined contributions (NDCs) and long-term strategies, containing each country’s pledged contribution to global mitigation. A key question is whether the collective action of all countries leads to the implementation of the Paris Agreement’s climate goals2,3. For this, countries agreed on a global stocktake process to periodically review collective progress and, if needed, stimulate additional efforts to meet the Paris Agreement’s global climate mitigation goals.

Several publications have already shown that the aggregated impact of NDCs is insufficient4,5. In addition, global emissions implied by nationally implemented policies are, collectively, even exceeding the global emissions levels projected under current NDCs4. This means that current NDCs and policies need to be strengthened. Scenarios from global integrated assessment models (IAMs) can provide guidance on how to do this. These include scenarios that provide information on how to implement reductions cost-optimally. However, in reality, it is not always possible to implement the measures included in these cost-optimal pathways6. For instance, influential societal actors might be able to block certain measures if they go against their interests. Market distortions can also make certain measures unattractive. Other solutions might lack societal support (e.g., carbon capture and storage), and also the rate at which a transition can be implemented may be slowed down (e.g., in the case of closing coal mines given the impact on coal miners and coal-dependent regions and communities). At the same time, however, there is also evidence of effective implementation of climate policies7. Here, good practice policies are defined as successfully implemented policies in one or more countries with a noticeable impact on greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions. In some cases, these policies are not even part of the cost-optimal mix suggested by models but could be easier to implement. It has been suggested that scaling up these good practice policies to other parts of the world might in the short-term be a more feasible and convincing strategy8,9,10,11,12,13.

First of all, history has shown that costs are only one factor influencing policy choices (see, e.g., Trutnevyte14, and the example of investments in renewable energy in the period that costs were still high). Other factors that influence policy choices include societal support, the influence of specific actors, and possible (perceived) co-benefits and trade-offs, including impacts on competitiveness. Second, such good practice policies have already been implemented in some countries, showing their effectiveness, at least in some places. Third, earlier work15 suggests that strengthening administrative and firm capabilities involved with monitoring, reporting and verification of emissions to support trading systems requires time and effort. Literature on policy sequencing16,17 shows how policies go through stages and at some point gain enough traction, experience, and political momentum to eventually move to efficient carbon pricing.

Fekete et al.7, Roelfsema et al.8, and Kriegler et al.9 investigated the impact of replicating such good practice policies in other parts of the world by focusing on global GHG emissions and indicators related to implementability (such as maximum annual average emissions reduction rate, carbon price increase per decade, or cumulative CCS deployment). Although helpful as a first step, this earlier work is limited by 1) the formulation of good practice policies at the global scale and 2) being based on a limited number of models. Better information on such good practice policies is needed to support the UNFCCC global stocktake in 2023.

Here, we build on the earlier work7,8,9, also going beyond relatively abstract cost-optimal pathways as guidance for policy-making by focusing on concrete policy measures that can be implemented to close the emissions gap. We do this for the first time using multiple models (both global and national) to assess a common set of reduction measures. These measures have been defined in consultation with national experts, making the scenarios more relevant (see Methods for details). The key scenario is referred to as the Bridge scenario, as it aims to bridge the gap between the ambition levels set out by countries by 2030 and those consistent with limiting global warming to 2 °C. This scenario includes a set of well-defined measures that can be implemented in the 2020–2030 period and go beyond the ambition of the NDCs (good practice policies), and that would still allow reaching the Paris climate goals by transitioning to a cost-optimal path towards 2 °C after 2030 (see Methods), assuming that governments prepare the ground for comprehensive (pricing) measures that are socially acceptable, e.g. through the use of revenues18. A focus on successfully implemented policies, as done in the Bridge scenario, will likely have near-term advantages in terms of political feasibility compared to an approach that focuses solely on cost-effectiveness (see above). The Bridge scenario, for example, allows to follow the steps identified in work on policy sequencing and thus move more smoothly than scenarios focusing on cost-effectiveness. The sequencing of policies can be attractive for other reasons as well. This allows, for instance, a gradual phase-in of climate policy per sector, e.g., to give households time to adjust. This concern applies particularly to investments related to residential energy use, where the lifetime of infrastructure typically extends beyond a few years. Additionally, the policy package that we apply is regionally differentiated, with higher-income countries taking more significant action in the 2020s. This can address some of the feasibility concerns observed in cost-optimal scenarios, allocating mitigation efforts to low-income countries in the near term (given the high potential for low-cost options, but with considerable feasibility concerns). We show that the Bridge scenario closes two-thirds of the emissions gap between NDC and 2 °C scenarios by 2030 and enables a pathway in line with the 2 °C goal when combined with more comprehensive pricing measures after 2030. Our analysis suggests that early action via these good-practice policies is less costly than a delay in global climate cooperation.

Results

In order to discuss the possible impacts of the Bridge scenario, we compare it to four other scenarios, i.e., the impacts of current policies (CurPol), the conditional NDCs (NDCplus), and the models’ cost-optimal pathways towards 2 °C (starting immediately: 2Deg2020, and with a delay: 2Deg2030) (see Methods and Supplementary Information for more details). For the first two scenarios, the current policies and NDCs were extended beyond 2030 by assuming equivalent effort, i.e., by extrapolating the equivalent carbon price in 2030, using the GDP growth rate of the different regions up to 2050 for the extrapolation (see Supplementary Methods). For the Bridge scenario, the defined set of measures was implemented up to 2030 (Table 1) and a cost-optimal path towards 2 °C was implemented after 2030 (see Supplementary Methods). A full description of the scenarios and additional results can be found in the Supplementary Information. In the context of the global stocktake, here we focus on the results at the global level and several large countries, while more detailed national-level results by national models can be found elsewhere11.

Table 1 The good practice policies that were assumed to be replicated globally in the Bridge scenario, with differentiated targets for high-income and low-/medium-income countries, adapted from earlier analysis of good practice policies7,8,9.

A bridge over the emissions gap

The model outcomes (Fig. 1 and Supplementary Figs. 8 and 9) show that the CurPol and NDCplus scenarios both fall considerably short of the emission reductions needed to limit global warming to 2 °C (consistent with earlier work). In contrast, the good practice policies included in the Bridge scenario can reduce GHG emissions close to the needed levels in 2030, followed by a longer-term trajectory similar to the ambitious benchmark of 2Deg2020. The Bridge scenario has a less steep reduction than the 2Deg2030 scenario in the 2030s, offering a pathway that largely closes the 2030 emissions gap without adding substantial challenges in the 2030s and 2050s. The emissions gap is defined as the difference between the NDCplus scenario and the 2Deg2020 scenario (median: 11.8 GtCO2eq). The Bridge scenario closes that global emissions gap by 7.2 GtCO2eq or 60% (median, range 26–275%) by 2030 and compensates the slower start by a slightly deeper emission reduction in 2050, 106% (92–112%). Some recently submitted NDCs could not be considered as they came after the cut-off date of this work. Based on the Synthesis report by the UNFCCC19, global emissions levels under the NDCs would be 398 Mt CO2eq lower in 2030 when taking these into account (i.e., 3.4% of the median emissions gap found here and 5.5% of the 2030 emissions reductions under the Bridge scenario). Compared to a 1.5 °C scenario instead of 2Deg2020 (1.5 °C scenarios were not run here but included from the CD-LINKS project4 for comparison), the global emissions gap would be closed by 31% (21–57%) by 2030 and by 81% (71–85%) by 2050. The difference in 2030 emissions between the NDCplus and 2Deg2020 is closed by 16% in the USA, 49% in India, 56% in the EU and 68% in China.

Fig. 1: Global GHG emissions (Gt CO2eq/year) between 2010 and 2050, as projected by the global models.
figure 1

Vertical bars: model range in 2050. Circles: model median in 2050. Thick solid lines: median. Grey: 1.5 °C scenarios from the IPCC SR1.5 database are included for comparison (a selection was made to cover the same models as represented here, with most similar scenario set-up, i.e., the 1.5 °C scenarios developed in the CD-LINKS project4). Projections for the Bridge scenario without the carbon tax measure are shown in Supplementary Fig. 7, for NDCplus variant NDC_2050convergence in Supplementary Fig. 8, and for 2050—2100 in Supplementary Fig. 9.

Supplementary Fig. 1 shows the national rates of GHG emissions reductions in the Bridge scenario, compared to the CurPol, NDCplus, and cost-optimal cases (immediate: 2Deg2020 and delay: 2Deg2030). In contrast to the increase in GHG emissions under current policies in some countries, emissions decline everywhere in the Bridge scenario, especially in the 2030–2050 period. In most countries, the Bridge scenario shows smaller reductions than the immediate action 2Deg2020 scenario in the short term (2030), and smaller reductions than the 2Deg2030 scenario in the longer term (2050). As such, good practice policies can constitute an alternate pathway in line with limiting global warming to 2 °C, without relying on carbon pricing alone as in cost-optimal scenarios, while not significantly increasing the burden in the 2050s.

Which measures have the largest effect on emissions?

The emissions gap between the NDCplus and 2Deg2020 scenarios amounts to approximately 12 GtCO2eq in 2030 (model median). The Bridge scenario closes this gap with 60% (a 7.2 GtCO2eq reduction). The energy supply sector (through higher renewable energy share, electrification, energy efficiency improvement) is the largest contributor to emissions reductions between the NDCplus and Bridge scenarios, both in 2030 and in 2050 (Fig. 2 and Table 2). In most models, mitigation of non-CO2 emissions, the transport sector (zero-carbon vehicles and efficiency improvements), and AFOLU (notably in 2030) also play an important role. This indicates potential to enhance ambition in specific areas, which will need to be explored at the national level.

Fig. 2: Contribution of each sector to emission reductions between the NDCplus and Bridge scenario (negative values denote an increase in emissions between NDCplus and Bridge, and are indicated with hashes).
figure 2

First bar: Emissions by sector in 2015. Second bar: emissions by sector in 2030 (panel a) and 2050 (panel b), under NDCplus. Third—ninth bar: emission reduction in AFOLU (Agriculture, Forestry, and Other Land Use), industry, buildings, transport, energy supply, industrial processes, non-CO2 emissions. Last bar: emissions by sector in 2030 (panel a) and 2050 (panel b), under Bridge. The IMAGE model is shown here as an illustrative example; full model ranges are shown in Table 2, while individual model results are shown in the SI (Supplementary Fig. 5). In addition, Supplementary Fig. 6 shows the sectoral contributions to emission reductions between the Bridge and 2Deg2020 scenarios in 2030.

Table 2 Share of sector in total GHG reduction from NDCplus to Bridge scenario (%), model range: minimum—maximum (median). AFOLU: Agriculture, Forestry, and Other Land Use.

Changes in energy and land-use systems

Figure 3 shows projected changes in energy and land-use systems under five scenarios: CurPol, NDCplus, Bridge, 2Deg2020, and 2Deg2030. The Bridge scenario significantly increases mitigation action compared to the CurPol and NDCplus scenarios. In fact, on several indicators, the prescribed policies (Table 1 and Supplementary Tables) close the gap with the cost-optimal 2Deg2020 scenario almost completely. By 2050, the Bridge scenario is more ambitious than the 2Deg2020 scenario for many indicators, compensating for the delay with respect to the cost-optimal pathway. Figure 3 Panel a, for example, shows that the target to increase the renewable electricity share by 1.4% per year in the Bridge scenario leads to deployment far beyond the CurPol and NDCplus scenarios in 2050 (i.e., toward 70%, vs. around 50%), but similar to 2Deg2020 (in line with previous research20) and lower than 2Deg2030. In 2030, however, the Bridge scenario is similar to 2Deg2020, so it does not increase the global trend in terms of installing renewables in the short term (it may do so regionally, however, see Baptista et al11.). As a result of the assumed penetration of non-fossil fuelled vehicles, the Bridge scenario shows a significant increase in the share of electricity in transport, even more so in Bridge than in 2Deg2020 (Panel b). This starts in 2030, but manifests especially in 2050. However, in some models, the target to increase non-fossil fuelled vehicles actually leads to an increase of biofuel powered engines (Supplementary Fig. 2) rather than electrification (explaining the relatively large range), but less so than the 2Deg2030 scenario in 2050. Following CCS, efficiency improvement, and F-gas emission reduction targets in industry, industrial emissions (expressed as CO2 emissions from industrial processes as well as F-gases, panel c), are projected to decrease in Bridge slightly more so than in 2Deg2020 (by 2050). Because the measures in the buildings sector focus on energy efficiency improvements, the share of electricity in buildings (panel d) is not projected to change significantly in the 2030s, but Bridge makes up for that by 2050. Panel e shows that the afforestation policy leads to slightly more afforestation in 2030, followed by a large scale-up in 2050, but not as large as in 2Deg2030. As such, CO2 emissions from agriculture, forestry and other land-use (AFOLU) are projected to be reduced by 38% (model median) by 2030 and by 151% by 2050 in the Bridge scenario, relative to 2015 levels. Supplementary Fig. 3 shows the same indicators but for the NDCplus-convergence scenario instead of NDCplus: by 2050, the convergence scenario is closer to the Bridge scenario than NDCplus for most indicators. Supplementary Fig. 4, finally, shows the projected changes in the primary energy mix. Bridge sees lower total primary energy supply mainly due to the efficiency improvement and transport electrification measures, but not as low as 2Deg2020, and a shift from fossil fuels to renewable energy sources, especially by 2050. As a result of the scale-up of renewable energy, electrification of energy demand, and efficiency improvements, CO2 emissions from the energy sector are projected to decrease. The Bridge scenario has notable co-benefits: emissions of air pollutants such as black carbon, carbon monoxide, nitrogen oxides, organic carbon, sulphur, and volatile organic compounds are projected to decrease, compared to NDCplus (Supplementary Fig. 12).

Fig. 3: Projected changes in various indicators, for 2030 and 2050, for the CurPol, NDCplus, Bridge, 2Deg2020, and 2Deg2030 scenarios.
figure 3

Bars show model median, error bars show the full range, and symbols show individual model results. Panel a share of renewables in electricity production (%), panel b share of electricity in final energy demand of transportation (%), panel c Emissions of F-gases and industrial process CO2 emissions, relative to 2015 levels (%), panel d share of electricity in final energy demand of buildings (%), panel e total afforestation and reforestation (million ha).

Costs of building the bridge

While the good practice policies may have benefits in terms of social and political acceptability, earlier work9 has highlighted that a set of regulatory measures may be more costly than a comprehensive carbon pricing scheme, leading to a noncost-optimal transition across regions and sectors. A uniform price signal would ensure that mitigation happens first where costs are lowest, leading to the overall most efficient outcome, in absence of other market failures. Although unlikely to be achieved globally, this stylised assumption therefore remains a useful benchmark. Furthermore, climate action as represented in the Bridge scenario implies a more gradual path for emission reductions in the period 2020–2030 compared to the immediate implementation of the cost-optimal policy (2Deg2020). This delay can further raise costs of the Bridge scenario, depending on the evolution of technology costs. The salience of a carbon price, however, may also raise opposition especially from low-income households facing energy poverty and food-insecurity21, carbon-intensive regions and vulnerable trade-exposed industries that may complicate or delay its implementation22. Arguably, the good practice policies included in the Bridge scenario face lower feasibility barriers and could speed up climate action compared to a scenario in which only cost-optimal policy measures are pursued. A fair evaluation of the costs of the Bridge scenario therefore involves two comparisons: one with the immediate and cost-optimal climate policy (2Deg2020), and one with a delayed implementation of uniform carbon pricing, starting in 2030 (2Deg2030) which requires more disruptive action to meet the 2 °C target.

Our results (Fig. 4) indicate that although the Bridge scenario raises policy costs (as expressed by GDP cost per tonne CO2eq abated relative to the Current Policies scenario) in 2050 by more than 20% (1–38%) compared to an immediate implementation of a cost-optimal 2 °C scenario with globally uniform carbon prices (2Deg2020), it has lower policy costs (Fig. 4a) and carbon prices (Fig. 4b and Supplementary Fig. 10) in the near term (2030). The Bridge scenario also outperforms a delayed 2 °C scenario (2Deg2030, see Supplementary Methods) with costs being more than 10% (-6–33%) lower in 2050. As such, our analysis suggests that early but noncost-optimal action is preferred over climate policy delay.

Fig. 4: Cost indicators for the Bridge scenario, compared to the other scenarios.
figure 4

Panel a GDP (in market exchange rates, MER) loss (relative to the CurPol scenario) in Bridge, relative to 2Deg2020 (dark orange) and 2Deg2030 (yellow), for 2030 (left) and 2050 (right). Panel b Carbon price (US$2010/tCO2), in 2030, 2040 and 2050. Bars: median, error bars: full range, symbols: individual models.

Interestingly, not all models in the ensemble agree on the size and sign of the trade-off between early and cost-optimal policy implementation. Multiple and counteracting effects are at play. Generally, good practice regulatory policies would raise costs particularly when the resulting energy system deviates strongly from the cost-optimal one. If the necessary changes are obvious, or when there are low-hanging fruits for climate policy, then a similar outcome may be achieved through regulation and carbon prices. The phase-out of coal and the scale-up of renewable power generation technologies23,24,25 may be an example that comes close (Supplementary Fig. 11 shows that investments in the electricity sector are projected to shift from fossil fuels to renewables). However, for other trade-offs, such as efficiency improvements versus fuel shift, or the allocation of emission reductions across sectors, a mix of regulatory measures that leads to an outcome resembling the cost-optimal one may be more difficult to achieve. Therefore, while regulatory policies can be a pragmatic entry-point for climate policy, cost-efficiency in the medium and long-term (beyond 2050) is more easily achieved via comprehensive carbon pricing schemes across all sectors and regions to avoid inter-sectoral and inter-regional leakage12. The costs of delaying climate action, on the other hand, depend on technological progress and the availability and scalability of negative emission technologies (NETs) in the future, among others26. For three out of four models that capture economic growth endogenously, the costs of delay outweigh the additional cost of regulatory good practice policies in 2050.

An advantage of the regulatory measures as implemented in the Bridge scenario is that carbon prices remain at lower levels in the near term, which may facilitate public acceptability and implementation of carbon pricing schemes with a broad sector coverage. If political consensus in favour of a comprehensive pricing scheme is not found over time, then a further intensification of the good practice policies may serve as a practical way forward to close the emissions gap. At the same time, the advantages of good practice policies in terms of acceptability may be challenged if ambitious climate targets bring cost elements to the forefront of the political debate.

Hence, our results suggest that a global roll-out of good practice policies can be a useful approach to close the emissions gap in the near term, while their role in climate policy in the longer term should be reconsidered in the context of a broader policy mix16, including carbon pricing27.

Discussion

Parties to the Paris Agreement were supposed to submit updated NDCs and communicate their long-term strategies to the UNFCCC in 2020. Due to the COVID-19 pandemic, these timelines have been delayed and some countries have announced that they will not submit an updated NDC, while some others have not increased ambition in their updated NDC. However, scaling up climate ambition and action remains necessary to keep the Paris Agreement goals within reach. As the emissions gap seems hard to close, we built a set of relevant scenarios that may provide a pathway based on successful examples of policies. The mitigation measures were defined in a two-way interaction with country experts and assumptions were adjusted for different regions if necessary. These scenarios, especially the good practice policies (Bridge scenario), can support the ratcheting up of mitigation ambition of NDCs.

Although the granularity of the Bridge scenario has improved in terms of country differentiation compared to earlier studies, some limitations remain. In most cases, we only distinguished high-income and low-/middle-income countries, which (while an advance on existing scenarios) is only a second-best option. However, we did not find good arguments for country-specific groupings in policy categories other than afforestation, where the groupings are motivated by explicit afforestation targets in the respective NDCs. Differentiating by income group is a pragmatic approach that was approved by stakeholders from various countries. While the measures were assessed to be implementable, this might not always be the case when moving to the country-level. Therefore, Baptista et al11. discuss the same set of scenarios in the context of national feasibility considerations. Future work could further analyse the sustainable development implications of the Bridge scenario, for example, whether it has synergies with the goal to eradicate poverty. The other way around, a bridge scenario could be developed that takes the sustainable development goals as a starting point to identify nationally relevant areas for increased ambition in the 2030s.

Models implemented the set of measures in different ways. For example, not all models were able to implement all measures related to non-CO2, given their scope; while others show relatively cheap abatement and high potential to implement measures in the 2030s, resulting in a large range for the sector’s share in emission reductions. The ranges, however, do tell a robust story about the Bridge scenario in relation to the reference scenarios. Although set at a relatively low level, the carbon price measure was the single most effective policy in the 2030s. Removing it from the set of measures resulted in significantly higher emissions (Supplementary Fig. 7). However, as many countries or regions already have a form of carbon pricing, it deserves a spot in the selection of good practice policies, especially given the differentiated timelines and pricing levels assumed in the Bridge scenario. Finally, we have not considered the impact of the COVID-19 pandemic quantitatively, effectively assuming a full recovery without significant effect on long-term, global emissions25. The policy measures explored here, however, can inform governments that aim for green recovery packages28, by showing potential for ratcheting up mitigation ambition with a concrete set of measures.

We have shown that good practice policies can help to reach the 2 °C target in the long-term. They ensure closing the global emissions gap between NDCs and a cost-optimal 2 °C scenario by two-thirds (model median) by 2030. After 2030, more ambitious measures are needed. Such a Bridge scenario leads to lower energy sector emissions due to scale-up of renewable energy, electrification of energy demand, and efficiency improvements, and to lower land-use emissions due to afforestation—at levels and rates of change that are somewhat less than the 2Deg2020 case and less than the 2Deg2030 case. The scenario is still in a position that allows meeting the 2 °C goal, and, importantly, is less disruptive than 2Deg2030. However, although we included a wide set of good practice policies, they are jointly insufficient to put the world on track to meet the 1.5 °C target. The Bridge scenario further illustrates that good practice policies alone—without implementation of additional instruments such as a comprehensive carbon pricing scheme—are not enough to reach the 2 °C target. The Bridge scenario raises policy costs (as expressed by GDP loss per tonne of CO2 abated relative to the CurPol scenario) in 2050 by approximately 20% compared to a cost-optimal 2 °C scenario (2Deg2020). When put in perspective of economic growth in the coming three decades, this 20% cost increase implies that annual economic growth rates in the Bridge would be around 0.02 percentage points below the annual GDP growth in 2Deg2020. The Bridge scenario outperforms the delayed 2 °C scenario (2Deg2030) with global economic impacts being more than 10% lower in 2050. As such, early but noncost-optimal action is preferred over climate policy delay. In the absence of immediate, all-encompassing and ambitious climate policy measures, therefore, a global roll-out and successful implementation of good practice policies can put the world on track to a 2 °C-compatible pathway without posing large additional challenges.

In short, acting stringently on 2 °C (2Deg2020) is needed, but, collectively, we are not on track (NDCplus). If we do not strengthen collective action until 2030, the best chance at limiting global warming may be 2Deg2030. However, if we manage to accelerate action until 2030 (Bridge), major disruption can be avoided, even if we do not fully reach 2Deg2020. These results illustrate that short-term (2030) implementation of practical regulation-based policies is preferable over delayed climate action. At the same time, the institutional set-up should aim to avoid inefficient policy lock-in, as more efficient instruments may gain political and societal support over time.

Methods

Models

Both national and global model teams followed the same scenario protocol for comparability. The global models included here are: AIM/CGE29, COPPE-COFFEE30, IMAGE31, MESSAGEix-GLOBIOM32, POLES33, PROMETHEUS34, REMIND-MAgPIE35, TIAM-Grantham36, WITCH-GLOBIOM 5.037. National-level results are presented in Baptista et al11.

Scenarios

In line with the global stocktake, the ratcheting up mechanism has been applied in constructing the scenario protocol (see Supplementary Methods for the full protocol text and Supplementary Tables for the detailed lists of good practice policies). This means that the scenarios build upon one another in terms of ambition and modelling assumptions. The Current policies scenario is the least ambitious and the 2 °C scenario is the most ambitious.

Reference scenarios

The Current policies (CurPol) scenario incorporates middle of the road socioeconomic conditions throughout the century, based on the second marker baseline scenario from the Shared Socioeconomic Pathways (SSP2)38. It also assumes that climate, energy and land-use policies that are currently ratified are implemented (cut-off date 1 July 2019).

The NDC-plus scenario builds further upon the CurPol scenario and assumes that the conditional NDCs (both unconditional and conditional NDC actions) as submitted by April 2020 are implemented by 2030. After 2030, the scenario reflects continuation of effort (see below).

Bridge scenario

The Bridge scenario builds upon the CurPol scenario and assumes that certain good practice policies, which have shown to be effective in some countries7,8,9, will be implemented globally from 2020 until 2030 (Supplementary Table 1 in Supplementary Data lists the good practice policies, while Supplementary Table 2 gives an overview of their implementation in models, with the implemented shares ranging from 44% to 94%). After 2030, the Bridge scenario transitions to a 2 °C scenario following a cost-effective pathway (see below). The set of policies was defined in dialogue with national model teams, granting a more realistic scenario narrative (for more details, see the Supplementary Information). This was done in multiple rounds. First, national modelling teams responded to the proposed good practice policies (based on literature), considering whether these policies could be realistically implemented in their countries and, if not, what other target levels or years would be feasible. These teams cover Australia, Brazil, Canada, China, EU, India, Indonesia, Japan, Republic of Korea, Russia, United States; i.e., approximately 75% of global emissions. Second, the policy list was adjusted to differentiate country groups, regarding the timing and stringency of the targets. Third, some national models ran the refined scenarios and provided feedback, upon which the list was further refined. As such, we eventually defined two country groups (high-income and middle-/low-income), and in some cases three (adding Other, with different definition per measure), which were found to offer enough differentiation to be nationally relevant while still adhering to a common set of policy measures. Finally, all national and global model teams ran the agreed set of scenarios.

Country differentiation of good practice policies

A distinction is made between low/medium-income and high-income countries in terms of timing and stringency of good practice policy targets. The AFOLU sector’s measures are differentiated mostly in terms of stringency, not timing, considering the current differences in efficiency between high- and lower-income countries. Afforestation rates have a more specific country differentiation, based on NDC ambition. Energy supply measures are rather similar between countries as these are already more widespread, with the exception of coal phase-out, where low-income countries would need more time. Measures in the buildings sector are differentiated in terms of timing (overall energy intensity of buildings and oil boilers) as well as stringency (efficiency of appliances and renovation rate) given the different starting points and future service demand in country groups. For industry, the CCS measure was differentiated in timing only, as the development of the technology has a global nature, but its implementation may encounter different institutional barriers between higher and lower-income countries. For adipic/acid production, no differentiation was applied as significant emissions reductions are already technically possible. For F-gases, the differentiation is in line with the Kigali Agreement. Transport measures were not differentiated for aviation due to its global nature, but vehicle measures were assumed to be less stringent in low-income countries given different starting points. Given the more abundant use of landfilling in lower-income countries, reductions in methane emissions from waste were assumed to be smaller than in high-income countries.

Carbon pricing

Finally, as opposed to Fekete et al7., carbon pricing is included as good practice policy, although it may be considered as a top-down policy of different nature than the other policies. Carbon pricing and emission trading schemes have been successfully implemented in various countries. Furthermore, previous work9 highlights that good practice regulatory policies should be considered as complements to pricing-based approaches. In the simulations, the carbon price applies to all gases and sectors, hence represents an idealized view of carbon pricing schemes. It does not take the highest carbon price currently observed as starting point, but rather an approach in which countries were divided in three tiers with different carbon price levels and timelines to be most relevant to the countries represented here, and to better reflect the current status of pricing measures, such as ETS39. As a variant and to analyse the effect of this measure, some models ran an additional scenario excluding the carbon price measure (see Supplementary Fig. 7).

Post-2030 assumptions

The Bridge scenario follows the good practice policies until 2030, after which the scenario transitions smoothly to the 2 °C scenario by remaining within the carbon budget consistent with the 2 °C target (1000 GtCO2 for 2011–2100). This was implemented via a carbon price, with the scenario converging from the regionally differentiated 2030 carbon prices as prescribed to a global carbon price in 2050 that is in line with the 2 °C carbon budget. It is assumed that the gradual implementation of climate policy in the 2020–2030 period can build up enough momentum (and technology development) to move to a more comprehensive climate policy after 2030. The 2 °C (2Deg2020 and 2Deg2030) scenarios assume that an average temperature increase of 2 °C without overshooting is reached by 2100 in a cost-effective way (starting from 2020 in 2Deg2020 and from 2030 in 2Deg2030). National modelling teams used a carbon budget derived from the global carbon budget of 1000 Gt CO2 in the period 2011–2100 (including 2011 emissions), as done in CD-LINKS (https://www.cd-links.org/)4. This global carbon budget represents a 66% probability of keeping global warming below 2 °C. Carbon budgets have been revised since the CD-LINKS project in such a way that 1000 Gt is even more stringent than previously. Cumulative CO2 emissions in the 2 °C scenarios (2Deg2020, 2Deg2030, and Bridge) are not all exactly 1000 Gt, but range from 788 Gt CO2 to 1540 Gt CO2 (2011–2100), which is still within the range considered to be in line with 2 °C.

For the CurPol and NDC-plus scenarios, a continuation of efforts after the target year was assumed. This was implemented by extrapolating the equivalent carbon price in 2030, using the GDP growth rate of the different regions up to 2050. The equivalent carbon price represents the value of carbon that would yield the same emissions reduction as the NDC policies in a region. If a region has a carbon price of zero while implementing the NDC in 2030, a minimum carbon price of 1 $/tCO2 in 2030 was assumed. If a region has a negative carbon price in 2030, the trajectory resulting from 1 $/tCO2 was offset to the model’s 2030 starting point. For land use, a carbon price ceiling of $200/tCO2 was applied.