Abstract
The EU Emission Trading System (ETS) is the oldest and currently the largest carbon market in the world, but its purpose of stimulating carbon emissions via trading profits remains unexamined. Based on the complete firm-level transaction records of the EU ETS Phases I and II, here we show that the participating firms’ trading profits and their emission abatements are positively correlated, and the correlation becomes stronger in Phase II than Phase I. Specifically, we observe that non-linearity exists in the correlation; higher firm-level emission abatements can realize larger trading profits. This pattern affects the market fairness, though it may be helpful to incentivise emission abatements. The correlation is more regulated in Phase II than it is in Phase I, thereby indicating that the Phase II is more mature. We also observe that the state-level abatements are largely driven by industrial giants.
Similar content being viewed by others
Introduction
Carbon emission trading has been proposed as a market-based policy instrument to reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions (mainly CO2) at the least possible cost. The European Union (EU) launched the European Union Emission Trading Scheme (EU ETS) on January 1, 2005 to fulfill the commitment of 8% reduction in GHG emissions by 2012 compared with 1990 proposed in the Kyoto Protocol1. Following the EU ETS, a series of carbon markets have been established successively, including the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative in the United States and the Pilot Carbon Trading Markets in China2,3. However, whether the incentives offered by such markets can be realized in emission abatements needs to be examined, because similar markets are continuously implemented worldwide2,3,4,5.
The EU ETS is a popular topic in the carbon market literature6,7,8,9,10,11,12,13,14,15,16,17,18,19,20,21,22,23,24,25,26 because it is the oldest and currently the largest carbon market in the world. The EU ETS covers over 11,000 installations from various industrial sectors across all EU member states and even non-EU countries such as Norway, Iceland, and Liechtenstein2,3. It is a cap-and-trade system, where a finite quantity of emission permits, namely the Eurpean Union Allowances (EUAs), is granted to the participating firms. There also exist two other tradable permits, i.e., the Emission Reduction Units (ERUs) and the Certified Emission Reductions (CERs). Firms report their annual carbon emissions to the authorities and surrender equivalent permits, each of which entitles its holder to emit 1 tonne of CO2. The surpluses or shortages of the permits are related to the quantity of one’s abatements for trading, thereby influencing the firms’ tradings.
Previous studies investigated various aspects related to the operation of the EU ETS, including market efficiency7,8,9, allowance allocation9,10,11, pricing mechanism12,13,14,15,16,17,18,19,20, trade frictions21, and market stability reserve22. Moreover, the EU ETS has an influence on stock markets23,24,25,26, energy markets27,28,29,30,31, and energy-intensive industries such as power32, metallurgical33, and transport industries34,35. However, little effort has been exerted on the incentiving effect of allowance trading on abatements; the market incentives are supposed to motivate the emitters to spontaneously and continuously reduce their GHG emissions. To date, this issue has never been quantitatively investigated, even though the EU ETS has been operating for over a decade.
The realization of the market incentives of the EU ETS is supposed to be guaranteed by two major safeguards. First, the abatements for trading are positively correlated to trading profits; higher profits ought to be acquired from more carbon abatements, while higher expenses shall be paid due to insufficient abatements. Since emission reduction is a long-term compaign3,36,37, firms should achieve abatements continuously, and the cap-and-trade market would provide incentives to support such efforts. Second, market regulation aims at constraining potential manipulation of dominant participants, thereby ensuring market fairness. Although cumulative market incentives can stimulate firms to abate their emissions continuously, it has potentials to endow big players with the market power, which could jeopardize the market fairness. However, to the best of our knowledge, the effectiveness of these safeguards remains unexamined.
Focusing on the subjects of the Phase I and II, this study examines the effectiveness of the market incentives that aims at stimulating abatements for trading. In detail, we reviewed the correlation between first the profits of firms (i.e., emitters) acquired from trading physical carbon allowances (defined as trading profits and denoted as profits r), and second the emission abatements for trading (the gaps between the allocated (and obtained from auctions, i.e., baseline emissions) and the surrendered allowances (i.e., actual emission), denoted as gap g), in a complete phase. Different types of abatements are illustrated in the Supplementary Discussion: Decomposition of emission abatements.
We aggregate the cash flows of all physical transactions of EUAs, CERs, and ERUs at their corresponding daily prices. The resulting values of the cash flows are considered as the trading profits (i.e., profits from allowance trading). Although the use of the daily values may cause deviations in the daily cash flows of individual firms, such deviations would not affect the cash flow distribution of all firms in a complete phase. The same principle is applicable for the daily-based stock market analysis. Therefore, the use of daily carbon prices does not affect the outcomes of this research, though using high-frequency prices could improve the accuracy of cash flow calculation. The data of the allocated and surrendered allowances are obtained from the compliance records. The impact of the firms’ characteristics and other external factors, such as macroeconomics, are excluded, since such factors are irrelevant to our objective of examining the impact of incentives on abatements.
The contribution of this study is fourfold. First, based on the complete firm-level trading records of Phase I and II in the EU ETS, we observe that emission abatements and trading profits are generally positively correlated. The effectiveness of the market incentives has been empirically verified, as abatements can be realized into profits. Second, using a quantile regression, we find the presence of non-linearity in the positive correlation between trading profits and emission abatements. Higher abatements have been realized greater profits; the Matthew effect (i.e., the rates of return of participants are positively correlated to their profit levels) exists in the EU ETS. Despite the pattern being helpful in stimulating carbon abatements, it grants big players with manipulative market power, thereby damaging the market fairness. Third, our findings suggest that the EU ETS is more mature in Phase II than in Phase I, as the incentives were given to participants in a fairer manner; the positive coefficient between r and g becomes smaller in Phase II than that in Phase I. Moreover, in Phase II, the extreme trading patterns are controlled and the Matthew effect is weakened. Lastly, we find that industrial giants play a decisive role in determining the state-level correlation between trading profits and emission abatements. Since big firms have higher rates of return in the allowance trading, their abatements and tradings require specific attention.
Results
Correlating profits and abatements
Figure 1 presents the complete quantile distribution. It shows that the density function shifts as the conditional quantile increases, which is evidence that the relation between r and g is non-linear. The presence of location shift proves that the relationship can be modeled by the quantile regression.
Table 1 summarizes the descriptive statistics of the estimated r of firms with different g quantiles. There are four observations on firm-quantiles relationship. First, the mean values of r increases as the values of g increases, thereby indicating that higher gaps correspond to higher profits. In other words, GHG abatements are financially rewarded in the cap-and-trade system. Second, as g increases, the standard deviation increases together with a decrease of the Kurtosis value. These results can be explained by a wide positive gap, which exerts low pressure on the firms to surrender allowances, thereby providing firms with diversified options to trade their extra allowances. Consequently, the range of the trading profits of firms tend to be wider than those of firms with narrow gaps. Third, the skewness values are positive in all the quantiles, thereby indicating that only a few firms can profit more highly than their sample average. This phenomenon is considerably significant in Phase I. Fourth, the Kurtosis value decreases with increasing gap level, thereby indicating that firms with wide gaps apparently obtain their profits unevenly.
This quantile regression results (Fig. 2) unveils three major findings about the effect of market incentives on emission abatements in the EU ETS. First, the coefficients of β(τ) are above zero in all quantiles, as well as in both phases, thereby indicating that abatements for trading can be well-realized as trading profits; it is common in other forms of market. Second, the estimated coefficients of β(τ) are greater in the higher quantiles than those in the lower ones; the presence of the Matthew effect is observed in the EU ETS. This observation shows that higher marginal profits go hand in hand with higher abatements, the realization of trading profits for emitters of different abatement levels is non-linear. Third, the increment of β(τ) is approximately linear in Phase I, but it becomes an S-shaped trend in Phase II. In addition, the range of β(τ) is much wider in Phase I than in Phase II. This difference implies that the Matthew effect is stronger in Phase I, while such effect is weakened in Phase II. Although promoting more abatements tends to be generally preferable, such unlimited markets incentives are not fair; advantageous emitters tend to gain the manipulative market power, thereby heavily influencing the allowance transactions. Under this consideration, the abatement motivations of the other emitters could be weakened, as they cannot acquire sufficient mariginal profits from allowance trading. On the contrary, the market becomes more mature and fair, provided that the effect of market incentives is moderate.
In the processed g–r coordinate system, the distribution of the firms’ coordiantes in Phase I is more dispersive, whereas firms’ coordinates in Phase II are clustered. The patterns of firms’ trading performance in the heat maps are generally compatible with the quantile regression results because the majority of the participating firms are concentrated in small linear zones around the origin of the g–r coordinate system. For Phases I and II, the distributions of the grids with more firms are similar to the overall distributions of all the participating firms. This finding indicates that the distributions of firms’ trading performance in the g–r coordinate system have multiscale fractal characteristics, thereby proving that the g–r coordinate system is robust. The linearity of Phase II is more evident than that of Phase I because the distribution of firms in the heat map of Phase II (Fig. 3b) is considerably linear and symmetric. Figure 3 provides further evidence to support the claim that EU ETS gradually reaches maturity in Phase II, as non-linearity in the realization of emission abatements is reduced. It implies that the extreme r–g patterns are more regulated in Phase II. Based on the firm-level empirical analysis, we confirm that the incentiving effect is valid and the market has matured.
Trading profits at state-level
To further examine the incentivizing effect of the cap-and-trade system, we investigate the effect of market incentives on carbon abatements in the allowance trading of each EU ETS member state. Figure 4 summarizes this correlation of all participating states.
Figure 4 shows that the majority of the participating states are well-ordered, whereas several abnormal states (i.e., states that are not in the clustered part of the linear sector) are highlighted. In Phase I, the UK had positive trading profit with a negative allowance gap. Germany made the highest profit, but its abatement was nearly zero. France gained an increased positive trading profit from its positive abatement. Poland profited slightly from the market, although it had the highest abatement. Spain had the lowest trading profit and allowance gap. In Phase II, Germany held both the lowest trading profit and emission abatement. France had the second-highest abatement but recorded a trading loss from the EU ETS. Poland obtained high trading profit at low emission abatement. Romania gained the highest trading profit and the largest emission abatement. However, the state-level trading profits and emission abatements of the majority of the states have positive linear correlation. Therefore, we can classify these abnormal states into two categories: first states with deviated performance (i.e., the UK, Germany, and Poland in Phase I; and Germany, France, and Poland in Phase II); and second states with extreme trading patterns (i.e., France and Spain in Phase I, and Romania in Phase II). Figure 5 depicts the firm-level g–r correlations of these abnormal states.
Figure 5 reveals that the g–r correlations of the majority of the firms in these states in both phases are linear and positive. On the contrary, the state-level g–r correlation is disturbed by some firms with increased trading profits or wide gaps. In other words, the national trading patterns of the participating states in EU ETS are mainly determined by several domestic industrial giants because their r and g values are much higher than those of others. The quantile regression results (Fig. 2) can be attributed to the trading patterns of the participating firms because the majority of these firms behave in a similar manner. By contrast, only a few big firms contribute to most of the observed deviations.
These abnormal giants have three distinctive patterns. First, the distribution of the g–r correlations of these firms is relatively dispersive, thereby disturbing the state-level trading patterns. Typical examples include the UK in Phase I, Germany in Phase II, and France and Poland in both phases. This observation implies that firms did not accurately predict their emission levels or allowance values. Second, firms with high trading volumes amended the trading pattern of the state, even if the g–r correlations of most firms in the same state are abnormal. Germany in Phase I fits this scenario. We posit that firms with advanced low-carbon technologies have low expectations of allocated allowances. Moreover, only a few distinguishable firms have the chance of profiting from carbon allowance trading. Third, although the g–r coordinate of firms within the same state are generally linear, some participating firms evidently deviate from the general cluster. One typical example is Romania in Phase II.
In summary, the number of abnormal firms is limited and their distribution appears to be random and symmetric in EU ETS. This result implies that the cap-and-trade system is generally effective in reducing GHG emissions. The g–r cooridantes of the majority of the participating firms concentrate in the linear sector, thereby proving the high effectiveness of the incentivizing effect of the cap-and-trade carbon market. The trading profits of a single firm are determined by the gap of carbon allowances but are also under the influences of the decisions or characteristics of firms, such as market expectations and trading strategies. Our analysis suggests that firms’ trading profits are positively correlated with emission abatements for trading but will deviate owing to the presence of other influencing factors.
Discussion
Our analysis provides three important findings based on the unique complete firm-level transaction data set. First, the incentivizing effect of carbon allowance trading of the EU ETS is realized; we observe that the total trading profits of firms are positively correlated with their carbon abatements for trading. This finding reveals that as a market-based instrument to reduce carbon emissions, the cap-and-trade system is generally effective, even though large allowances were simply traded for compliance obligation3,12.
Second, we find that non-linearity exists in the correlations between trading profits r and emission abatements for trading g. This observation indicates that the firms of higher emission abatements can acquire greater profitability for carbon allowance trading; the presence of the Matthew effect in the allowance trading in the EU ETS is detected. Some participants have higher rates of return in both directions, thereby affecting the fairness of realizing the financial awards of emission abatements in the cap-and-trade market. This can be attributed to the inactive trading environment where the participants with bigger trading scale intentionally or unintentionally manipulate the market to some extent38. Yet, this pattern seems to be weakened in Phase II over Phase I, confirming that the EU ETS becomes more mature in the latter phase. This finding agrees with the extant macroeconomic literature that suggests the increasing maturity of EU ETS7,8. Stable value realization of emission abatements facilitates the financial management of carbon allowances, which are widely recognized as financial assets39,40,41,42,43,44 that influence a series of energy commodities such as crude oil and natural gas29.
Our final observation was obtained in the comparison of the state-level r–g correlations of the participating states in the carbon market. The majority of the states and firms have similar trading patterns because they profited proportionally to their abatements for trading. Meanwhile, certain companies with significant allowance gaps affected their countries significantly. For example, in Phase I, the UK had positive trading profit with a negative g, while Germany made the highest profit with a zero abatement for trading. The extant literature has reviewed the impact of EU ETS on the industrial sectors32,33,34,35. To the best of our knowledge, insufficient attention has been directed at the realization of national carbon abatements through firm-level trading in the scheme possibly owing to limited data availability. Accordingly, our unique firm-level trading data set fills in this knowledge gap. A direct implication of this finding for policy makers and administrators is that increased attention should be provided to monitor the transactions of these industrial giants. But this finding may be inappropriate to regulate firms’ trading behaviors in such a market. The abnormal firms may have at least one of the following features: conducting a few transactions and odd trading behaviors, e.g., conducting transactions only in certain periods. These transactions cause these firms to be overrewarded or overpunished. Hence, active and balanced transactions with directions (i.e., buy or sell) and timepoints selected based on market expectationn’ s can guarantee that firms are properly rewarded according to their gaps, thereby possibly improving the carbon abatement mechanism of the EU ETS. Among all the potential national differences that affect trading, the development of low-carbon technologies varies from one member state to another is worthy of in-depth investigation because of its influence on the majority of the participating firms at the state level.
Methods
Data aggregation
Our analysis is based on a unique firm-level data set that combines all transaction records in the Community Independent Transaction Log (CITL) of Phase I and the European Union Transaction Log (EUTL) of Phase II or the Kyoto Phase. The detailed aggregation procedure of this unique data set is presented in the Supplementary Method: Construction of firm-level trading data set. This unique data set can be regarded as the complete transaction log of Phases I and II allowances (. Allowance transaction data have been maximized in the microeconomic literature to identify the determinants of an emitter’s trading volume45, trading threshold46, trading activities47, effects of transaction costs48, and performance49. To the best of our knowledge, no research has constructed firm-level trading data in such comparable detail and so completely. Moreover, the data employed in the extant literature either only cover Phase I45,47,48 or fails to link installations to firms45,49. Using the unique microlevel trading data set, we aim to examine the effect of the market incentives that are provided by the cap-and-trade system on carbon abatements.
Model construction
To avoid the inequality of the data and find some potential non-linear relationships, we employ a quantile regression model to investigate the correlation between firm profits(r) and quantiles(g) in EU ETS:
where α(τ) is the intercept and ß(τ) is the quantile coefficient that depends on τ. The model is derived by specifying the τth conditional quantile as Qτ (r | g) and estimating α(τ) and ß(τ) as the solutions to the following equation50:
where ρτ(z) is a linear loss function defined as z(τ−1) if z < 0; otherwise, zτ.
We use 20 quantiles (i.e., 0.05, 0.10, 0.15,…, 0.95) in the analysis. All regression results for these quantiles are significant for the carbon trading data of Phases I and II can be found in Fig. 2a, 2b. The quantile regression results are based on the firm-level dataset. In addition, we employ heat maps to visualize the distributions of r and g in detail. The differences in the goodness-of-fit values of the different phases can be effectively explained visually via the heat maps (Fig. 3), in which r and g are processed as follows:
where sig(x) is a signal function.
The process and outcomes of robustness check is given in the Supplementary Method: Robustness check.
Reporting summary
Further information on research design is available in the Nature Research Reporting Summary linked to this article.
Data availability
The data sets generated during or analyzed in this study are available from the corresponding author upon any reasonable requests. The raw data that our firm-level trading data were derived from are available in the public domain: EUTL dataset (https://ec.europa.eu/clima/ets/). The firm-level data and the sub data in major countries are available on Figshare (https://doi.org/10.6084/m9.figshare.12034482.v1; https://doi.org/10.6084/m9.figshare.12034503.v1; https://doi.org/10.6084/m9.figshare.12034479.v2).
Code availability
The data, R codes of the statistical analysis, and the results are available from the corresponding author upon any reasonable requests.
References
Directive 2003/87/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 13 October establishing a scheme for greenhouse gas emission allowance trading within the Community and amending Council Directive 96/61/EC. Official Journal of the European Union 275 (25.10) (2003).
Green, J. F. Don’t link carbon markets. Nature 543, 484–486 (2017).
Newell, R. G., William, A., Pizer, W. A. & Raimi, D. Carbon market lessons and global policy outlook. Science 343, 1316–1317 (2014).
Fang, G., Tian, L., Liu, M., Fu, M. & Sun, M. How to optimize the development of carbon trading in China—Enlightenment from evolution rules of the EU carbon price. Appl. Energ. 211, 1039–1049 (2018).
Song, Y., Liu, T., Li, Y. & Liang, D. Region division of China’s carbon market based on the provincial/municipal carbon intensity. J. Clean. Prod. 164, 1312–1323 (2017).
Convery, F. J. Origins and development of the EU ETS. Environ. Resour. Econ. 43, 391–412 (2009).
Daskalakis, G. & Markellos, R. N. Are the European carbon markets efficient? Rev. Fut. Mark. 17, 103–128 (2008).
Daskalakis, G. On the efficiency of the European carbon market: new evidence from Phase II. Energ. Policy 54, 369–375 (2013).
Fell, H., Burtraw, D., Morgenstern, R. D. & Palmer, K. Soft and hard price collars in a cap-and-trade system: a comparative analysis. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 64, 183–198 (2012).
Georgopoulou, E., Sarafidis, Y., Mirasgedis, S. & Lalas, D. P. Next allocation phase of the EU emissions trading scheme: how tough will the future be? Energ. Policy 34, 4002–4023 (2006).
Böhringer, C., Hoffmann, T. & Manrique-de-Lara-Penate, C. The efficiency costs of separating carbon markets under the EU emissions trading scheme: a quantitative assessment for Germany. Energ. Econ. 28, 44–61 (2006).
Fan, Y., Jia, J., Wang, X. & Xu, J. What policy adjustments in the EU ETS truly affected the carbon prices? Energ. Policy 103, 145–164 (2017).
Seifert, J., Uhrighomburg, M. & Wagner, M. Dynamic behavior of CO2 spot prices. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 56, 180–194 (2008).
Cretí, A. & Joëts, M. Multiple bubbles in the European Union Emission Trading Scheme. Energ. Policy 107, 119–130 (2017).
Wang, J., Gu, F., Liu, Y., Fan, Y. & Guo, J. A big data study on the bidirectional interactions between trading behaviors and carbon prices in European Union Emission Trading Scheme. J. Clean. Prod. 224, 435–443 (2019).
Guo, J. et al. How do verified emissions announcements affect the comoves between trading behaviors and carbon prices? Evidence from EU ETS. Sustainability 10, 3255 (2018).
Daskalakis, G. Temporal restrictions on emissions trading and the implications for the carbon futures market: Lessons from the EU emissions trading scheme. Energ. Policy 115, 88–91 (2018).
Hintermann, B. Market power in emission permit markets: theory and evidence from the EU ETS. Environ. Resour. Econ. 66, 1–24 (2017).
Ibrahim, B. M. & Kalaitzoglou, I. A. Why do carbon prices and price volatility change?. J. Bank Fiance 63, 76–94 (2016).
Fan, Y., Liu, Y. & Guo, J. How to explain carbon price using market micro-behaviour? Appl. Econ. 48, 4992–5007 (2016).
Medina, V., Pardo, Á. & Pascual, R. The timeline of trading frictions in the European carbon market. Energ. Econ. 42, 378–394 (2014).
Perino, G. & Willner, M. Procrastinating reform: the impact of the market stability reserve on the EU ETS. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 80, 37–52 (2016).
Mo, J., Zhu, L. & Fan, Y. The impact of the EU ETS on the corporate value of European electricity corporations. Energ 45, 3–11 (2012).
Bushnell, J., Chong, H. & Mansur, E. T. Profiting from regulation: evidence from the European carbon market. Am. Econ. J. Econ. Policy 5, 78–106 (2013).
Tian, Y., Akimov, A., Roca, E. & Wong, V. Does the carbon market help or hurt the stock price of electricity companies? Further evidence from the European context. J. Clean. Prod. 112, 1619–1626 (2016).
Brouwers, R., Schoubben, F., Van Hulle, C. & Van Uytbergen, S. The initial impact of EU ETS verification events on stock prices. Energ. Policy 94, 138–149 (2016).
Bonenti, F., Oggioni, G., Allevi, E. & Marangoni, G. Evaluating the EU ETS impacts on profits, investments and prices of the Italian electricity market. Energ. Policy 59, 242–256 (2013).
Sousa, R., Aguiar-Conraria, L. & Soares, M. J. Carbon financial markets: a time–frequency analysis of CO2 prices. Phys. A Stat. Mech. Appl 414, 118–127 (2014).
Marimoutou, V. & Soury, M. Energy markets and CO2 emissions: analysis by stochastic copula autoregressive model. Energ 88, 417–429 (2015).
Zhang, Y. J. & Sun, Y. F. The dynamic volatility spillover between European carbon trading market and fossil energy market. J. Clean. Prod. 112, 2654–2663 (2016).
Višković, V., Chen, Y. & Siddiqui, A. S. Implications of the EU emissions trading system for the South-East Europe Regional Electricity Market. Energ. Econ. 65, 251–261 (2017).
Rogge, K. S. & Hoffmann, V. H. The impact of the EU ETS on the sectoral innovation system for power generation technologies – Findings for Germany. Energ. Policy 38, 7639–7652 (2010).
Moreno, B., García-Álvarez, M. T. & Fonseca, A. R. Fuel prices impacts on stock market of metallurgical industry under the EU emissions trading system. Energ 125, 223–233 (2017).
Heinrichs, H., Jochem, P. & Fichtner, W. Including road transport in the EU ETS (European Emissions Trading System): A model-based analysis of the German electricity and transport sector. Energ 69, 708–720 (2014).
Cui, Q., Wei, Y. & Li, Y. Exploring the impacts of the EU ETS emission limits on airline performance via the Dynamic Environmental DEA approach. Appl. Energ. 183, 984–994 (2016).
Fankhauser, S. & Hepburn, C. Designing carbon markets, part I: carbon markets in time. Energ. Policy 38, 4363–4370 (2010).
Fankhauser, S. & Hepburn, C. Designing carbon markets, part II: carbon markets in space. Energ. Policy 38, 4381–4387 (2010).
Balietti, A. C. Trader types and volatility of emission allowance prices. Evidence from EU ETS Phase I. Energ. Policy 98, 607–620 (2016).
Daskalakis, G., Ibikunle, G., & Diaz-Rainey I. The CO2 Trading Market in Europe: A Financial Perspective. In: Dorsman, A., Westerman, W., Karan, M., & Arslan, Ö. (eds) Financial Aspects in Energy. Springer, (Berlin, Heidelberg, 2011).
Rittler, D. Price discovery and volatility spillovers in the European union emissions trading scheme: a high-frequency analysis. J. Bank. Financ. 36, 774–785 (2012).
Schultz, E. & Swieringa, J. Catalysts for price discovery in the European Union emissions trading system. J. Bank. Financ. 42, 112–122 (2014).
Daskalakis, G., Psychoyios, D. & Markellos, R. N. Modeling CO2 emission allowance prices and derivative: evidence from the European trading scheme. J. Bank. Financ. 33, 1230–1240 (2009).
Balcilar, M., Demirer, R., Hammoudeh, S. & Nguyen, D. K. Risk spillovers across the energy and carbon market and hedging strategies for carbon risk. Energ. Econ. 54, 159–172 (2016).
Wen, X., Bouri, E. & Roubaud, D. Can energy commodity futures add to the value of carbon assets? Econ. Model. 62, 194–206 (2017).
Zaklan, A. Why do emitters trade carbon permits? Firm-level evidence from the European Emission Trading Scheme. DIW Berlin Discussion Paper No. 1275, P32 (2013).
Martin, R., Muûls, M., & Wagner, U. J. Trading behavior in the EU Emissions Trading Scheme. Preprint at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2362810 (2014).
Betz, R. A. & Schmidt, T. S. Transfer patterns in Phase I of the EU emissions trading system: a first reality check based on cluster analysis. Clim. Policy 16, 474–495 (2016).
Jaraitė-Kažukauskė, J. & Kažukauskas, A. Do transaction costs influence firm trading behaviour in the European emissions trading system. Environ. Resourc. Econ. 62, 583–613 (2015).
Liu, Y., Guo, J. & Fan, Y. A big data study on emitting companies’ performance in the first two phases of the European Union Emission Trading Scheme. J. Clean. Prod. 142, 1028–1043 (2017).
Koenker, R. Quantile Regression (Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 2005).
Acknowledgements
We would like to thank Prof. Samuel Fankhauser and Dr. Misato Sato from the Grantham Research Institute and Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy, London School of Economics; Prof. Michael Grubb from the Bartlett School of Environment, Energy and Resources, University College London; and Prof. Joachim Schleich from the Fraunhofer Institute for Systems and Innovation Research for their insightful comments on this manuscript. This study is financially supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Nos. 71671180, 71832013, 71804177, and 71690245), National Science and Technology Major Project (No. 2016ZX05040-001).
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Contributions
J.G. and F.G. proposed the original idea, conducted the analysis and wrote the manuscript. Y.L. provided the theory and methodology and prepared the plots. J.G., F.G., and Y.L. processed the data and participated in the statistical analysis. X.L., J.M., and Y.F. thoroughly revised the manuscript and provided advice on the analysis. X.L. corrected the methodology.
Corresponding authors
Ethics declarations
Competing interests
The authors declare no competing interests.
Additional information
Peer review information Nature Communications thanks the anonymous reviewer(s) for their contribution to the peer review of this work.
Publisher’s note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Supplementary information
Rights and permissions
Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this license, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.
About this article
Cite this article
Guo, J., Gu, F., Liu, Y. et al. Assessing the impact of ETS trading profit on emission abatements based on firm-level transactions. Nat Commun 11, 2078 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1038/s41467-020-15996-1
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1038/s41467-020-15996-1
This article is cited by
-
Easing financial constraints through carbon trading
Empirical Economics (2024)
-
Carbon pricing and aggregate macroeconomic performance in the Eurozone: a contribution to the climate policy debate using the EU ETS and Macroeconomic Performance Index
Environmental Science and Pollution Research (2024)
-
Decomposition of the site-level energy consumption and carbon dioxide emissions of the iron and steel industry
Environmental Science and Pollution Research (2024)
-
Carbon emission trading system and stock price crash risk of heavily polluting listed companies in China: based on analyst coverage mechanism
Financial Innovation (2023)
-
Correlation and causality between carbon and energy markets: a complexity perspective
Environmental Science and Pollution Research (2022)