Abstract
Following the financial crisis of 2007–2008, a deep analogy between the origins of instability in financial systems and complex ecosystems has been pointed out: in both cases, topological features of network structures influence how easily distress can spread within the system. However, in financial network models, the details of how financial institutions interact typically play a decisive role, and a general understanding of precisely how network topology creates instability remains lacking. Here we show how processes that are widely believed to stabilize the financial system, that is, market integration and diversification, can actually drive it towards instability, as they contribute to create cyclical structures which tend to amplify financial distress, thereby undermining systemic stability and making large crises more likely. This result holds irrespective of the details of how institutions interact, showing that policy-relevant analysis of the factors affecting financial stability can be carried out while abstracting away from such details.
Similar content being viewed by others
Introduction
Until the 1970s, ecologists widely believed that the stability of an ecosystem was generally enhanced by increasing complexity, as reflected in the presence of a large number of interactions between species. Yet seminal work by May1 showed that complexity can actually undermine stability. His analysis of a class of network models indicated that networks with a larger number of interactions (at fixed interaction strengths) were less stable, inspiring ecologists to begin searching for possible new sources of stability in specific topological motifs within food webs. In the wake of the financial crisis of 2007–2008, Haldane and May argued2 for the relevance of this insight to the stability of financial systems as well. Indeed, while the pre-crisis literature in economics and finance mostly viewed network complexity as helpful for stability, the application of network theory to finance3 has made it clear that complexity can destabilize the financial system4,5,6,7.
However, a precise understanding of how network complexity undermines stability has remained elusive. A growing body of work8,9,10,11,12,13,14,15 carries out stress tests on the financial system by computing the distribution of losses conditional upon a given pattern of shocks. To this end, one must rely on specific assumptions on the nature of the financial contracts and the distress propagation mechanisms. Following16,17, here we take a different approach: Rather than trying to compute the distribution of losses, we simply identify the conditions under which the system amplifies shocks. This allows to abstract from details on the nature of financial contracts.
In this paper we point out the existence of two general mechanisms that strongly influence the stability of financial networks. In particular, we show that two processes that increase the interaction between banks—market integration, which enlarges the number of banks participating in the financial system, and diversification, which leads to a proliferation of contracts—may lead to instability. Moreover, we show how such instability is associated with the emergence in the network of specific cyclic structures, which amplify financial distress. There are different types of connections between financial institutions, both direct such as interbank loans and indirect such as exposures to common assets17,18,19. Our results are derived in the context of systemic risk emerging from networks of direct exposures between financial institutions (in the following, ‘banks’ for brevity), which are modelled as directed weighted networks20,21,22,23 and which pose significant scientific challenges and comes with prominent policy and societal implications24.
Results
Interbank network
While many factors drive systemic risk, the literature has identified two main channels for the propagation of financial distress through direct exposures. The first is known as illiquidity contagion: If banks anticipate that their counterparties may incur losses, they will try to withdraw their liquid funds from them25,26, inducing them, in turn, to withdraw their funds from their own counterparties. Therefore, distress propagates from lenders to borrowers as their liquidity decreases. The second channel is the deterioration of interbank assets: lenders may reassess the value of their claims towards their borrowers under distress by taking into account the possibility that borrowers might default, and therefore might not be able to meet their obligations. This impacts the balance sheet of the lender, in which assets corresponding to interbank loans will decrease in value. Such accounting practice, called marking-to-market, is enforced by regulatory authorities for certain classes of interbank obligations. In this context, the devaluation of assets effectively generates losses for lenders, which can in turn be transmitted to their creditors11,27,28. Since the process of illiquidity contagion is essentially driven by the anticipation of the potential interbank asset deterioration, here we focus on the latter mechanism only, in line with most of the previous literature21,22,27.
Notice that most works based on the pioneering model of Eisenberg-Noe27 conclude that contagion through the network of interbank exposures would be empirically very small18,29. However, it has been shown that two assumptions in the modelling framework of Eisenberg-Noe imply by construction that interbank contagion has to be very small30: the fact that only the event of default affects the value of the obligation and the fact that all remaining assets of defaulting banks are recovered fully and immediately. Indeed, two reasons for why networks of direct exposures can still be important have been discussed in the literature. The first is the fact that counterparty default risk can amplify the so-called ‘balance-sheet contagion’31 due to overlapping portfolios32. The second reason is that ‘declines in credit quality can propagate losses well before any node has failed’29, as indeed modelled in a growing strand of work11,13,14,33. This argument finds empirical support in ref. 34, in which it is estimated that two thirds of the losses related to counterparty risk are due to mark-to-market devaluation of assets and one-third to defaults.
The equity E of a bank, that is, the difference between its total assets and liabilities, is an important variable in determining the financial health of a bank. In the literature on financial contagion11,27,28, a bank defaults as soon as its equity becomes negative, as it is unlikely that it will be able to repay its debts in full. The ratio between total assets and equity is called leverage and it is a coarse estimate of the riskiness of a bank, as it is related to the maximum loss on the assets that can be absorbed by the equity of the bank. While leverage is usually understood as a single number for each bank, the notion has been recently extended into the concept of leverage matrix13, whereby leverage is computed with respect to each specific asset class or counterparty. In particular, for a system of n banks here we consider the n × n interbank leverage matrix Λ, whose elements Λij are equal to the ratio between the nominal exposure of bank i towards bank j and the equity of bank i. The total interbank leverage of bank i is simply equal to . In fact, we will consider an adjusted interbank leverage matrix , where ρj is the recovery rate of bank j, that is, the fraction of its interbank assets recovered by creditors in case of default. Finally, let us denote the relative equity loss of bank i at time t as hi(t)=(Ei(0)−Ei(t))/Ei(0).
Starting from basic principles of financial accounting and under mild assumptions on the type of financial contracts among banks, we show that the relative equity loss of bank i can be written as a function of the relative equity loss of its counterparties and of the leverage matrix Λij, according to the following dynamics: , where p is the default probability of counterparty j as a function of its relative equity loss (see Supplementary Methods for the details). We now briefly argue that it is reasonable to assume that default probabilities are convex functions of the relative equity loss. In fact, the probability of default will be barely affected by small equity losses (as those due to daily fluctuations), while when a bank is close to default, even a small increment in equity losses can make a huge difference. This additional assumption allows us to characterize the stability of the system in terms of and , the largest eigenvalues of the matrices and , where . Since , we have three possible regimes: if the system is stable, if the system is unstable, while if the system could be either stable or unstable (see Supplementary Methods for a full proof). We note that the instability criterion depends on default probabilities, while the stability criterion does not, which is in accordance with the following intuition: it is always possible to make a financial system stable by having probabilities of default that increase slowly enough as equity losses increase.
Despite the considerable body of work on financial contagion, since there is no simple relationship between the topology of a network and λmax, the study of stability has been seldom carried out in this context. Notable exceptions are ref. 16, in which the stability analysis of the Furfine algorithm28 applied to the US CDS market has been conducted, and ref. 17, in which the stability of bipartite networks of overlapping portfolios has been probed through a mapping of the contagion dynamics onto a branching process. By building on these previous analyses, here we quantify the importance of cycles, and we highlight the existence of general mechanisms that might lead to the emergence of instability in the network of mutual exposures between banks.
Our starting point is the definition of pathway towards instability as a sequence of networks (represented here by their weighted adjacency matrices) Λ(0), Λ(1), …, Λ(k) such that (i) the dynamics corresponding to Λ(0) is stable for all choices of probabilities of default, (ii) there exist at least one choice of probabilities of default such that the dynamics corresponding to Λ(k) is unstable, and (iii) the average interbank leverage is the same for all the networks in the sequence. That the average interbank leverage does not change rules out trivial pathways towards instability; in fact, in the absence of such constraint, it would be easy to build sequences of interbank leverage matrices with larger and larger weights. The aforementioned stability criteria provide a simple way to check if a sequence of networks is a pathway towards instability: it will suffice to check that the largest eigenvalue of is smaller than one and that the largest eigenvalue of is larger than one. Based on the definition of pathway towards instability, here we show two important effects pertaining to financial instability that had remained uncovered so far and could have profound policy implications. First, even if the individual leverage of banks does not increase, a financial system can turn from stable to unstable as the number of banks increases (that is, the number of nodes in the network grows larger) like during a process of market integration. Second, even if the individual leverage of banks does not increase, a financial system can become unstable as the number of contracts among banks increases (that is, the number of edges in the network increases) like during a process of risk diversification. Notably, in both cases instability appears despite the fact that the assessment that each bank makes of its own risk profile does not change, because individual leverage levels remain constant. This means that market integration and risk diversification can make the system as a whole unstable. These results do not imply that such processes are detrimental per se, but that financial policies focusing only on individual banks, also known as micro-prudential policies, can have the opposite effect of increasing financial instability if they do not consider the system as a whole. As it will be clear further below, the origin of instability lies in the fact that in both processes banks get increasingly involved in multiple cycles (that is, closed chains) of contracts. Our results suggest to include the eigenvalue analysis of the leverage matrix among the tools to monitor financial stability.
Emergence of instability
In order to keep the notation agile, in the remainder of the paper we set recovery rates equal to zero, so that . If recovery rates are strictly larger than zero one simply has to compute instead of λmax. The relation between λmax and interbank leverage across banks becomes simple if all banks have the same interbank leverage or if the interbank network is a large Erdős-Rényi graph35. In the first case, via the Perron-Frobenius theorem, λmax is bounded by the smallest and largest sum over the columns of the interbank leverage matrix, that is, precisely by the smallest and largest interbank leverages. Hence, if all banks have the same interbank leverage , it must be also equal to λmax. The second case is similar to the May-Wigner theorem about the instability of model ecosystems1 in which species interact through a large Erdős-Rényi graph. The main difference is that in our case interactions between banks are described by the leverage matrix Λ, which is non-negative, while the interactions between species in ecosystems are described by a matrix whose elements can have unspecified sign. In the Supplementary Methods we prove that, for n→∞, in this case , the average interbank leverage across banks. Therefore, in both cases the system is unstable whenever .
When relaxing either of the two assumptions (homogeneity of leverage, or large size together with randomness of the graph), finer details of the network structure become important. For instance, because the theorem only holds in the limit of large size graphs, there exist small Erdős-Renyi graphs that are stable although they have . An example of a small size network that is extremely important for policy is the network of the Global Systemically Important Banks36, comprising about 30 banks. Let us start from a small and stable Erdős-Renyi graph with and to connect more banks to the network (by keeping and the number of contracts per bank constant). Eventually, the system will grow large enough to become unstable because the theorem will have to hold in the limit of large graphs (see Supplementary Fig. 1 for an example). This is an example of a previously unreported phenomenon that we call pathways to instability, that is, the existence of trajectories in the space of graphs along which financial networks turn from stable to unstable, although at each point along the trajectory the system satisfies a global constraint on the average interbank leverage. While the theorem above guarantees the existence of pathways towards instability only for Erdős-Rényi graphs, one can perform numerical experiments to investigate additional topologies as well37,38,39. In analogy with Erdős-Rényi graphs, one starts with stable graphs with , increases the number of banks by keeping both the topology and the average interbank leverage constant, and checks if at the end of the process the graphs become unstable. In Supplementary Figs 2–4 we show that pathways towards instability exist also for regular random graphs, scale-free graphs and core-periphery graphs. The last example is especially relevant, as empirical studies40,41 have found real interbank networks to be compatible with the core-periphery topology. Therefore, we build realistic models of interbank networks by generating random core-periphery graphs using the parameters in ref. 41. However, interbank exposures are confidential and usually available only to regulators. The information that is publicly available is, for each bank, the total amount of interbank assets and the total amount of interbank liabilities. In order to cope with this problem, several techniques that allow to reconstruct exposures based on the limited publicly available information have been developed42,43,44. In particular, we reconstruct interbank exposures using the RAS algorithm45, which assigns exposures so that, for each bank, the total interbank assets and the total interbank liabilities match the values reported in their balance sheets (see Supplementary Methods for additional details).
In general, the system is unstable if and only if there exists an unstable strongly connected component (that is, a directed subgraph in which each node is reachable indirectly by any other). The Perron-Frobenius theorem only guarantees that the largest eigenvalue of a strongly connected component is between the minimum and the maximum interbank leverage across banks. Hence, a sufficient condition for instability (stability) is that the interbank leverage of all banks is larger (smaller) than one. However, for the years from 2008 to 2013, the smallest interbank leverage of European banks is very close to zero, while the 95th percentile of its distribution is between 2.5 and 6, meaning that the Perron-Frobenius bounds are not informative enough on the largest eigenvalue, and we need to look more closely at the topology of the network. For instance, for graphs without cycles (that is, directed acyclic graphs, DAGs) λmax is always equal to zero, implying that the presence of cycles is a necessary condition for instability (although not sufficient). Intuitively, a cycle amplifies distress propagation if the product of the weights of its edges is larger than one (we refer to this as an individually unstable cycle). Interestingly, a policy recommendation included in Basel III Accords46 encourages banks to have the largest single exposure smaller than a fraction of their equity, so that Λij<1 for all i, j. The policy is thus effective in avoiding this source of instability.
However, the presence of individually unstable cycles, although sufficient, is not necessary for instability. Consider the two examples in Fig. 1. In particular, the second is a simple case of core-periphery network architecture, a frequently observed pattern in empirical interbank data40. In both cases, not only the largest single exposure policy is implemented, but (depending on the value of the parameter w) the average interbank leverage can be smaller than one. These two conditions could intuitively suggest that the system is stable. Yet, λmax is larger than one and the system is unstable. The reason is that there are banks involved in multiple cycles. More precisely, a sufficient condition for having λmax>1 is that there exist two integers i, k such that (Λk)ii>1, that is, that there exists a bank i such that the sum, over all the cycles of length k from i to itself, of the products of the elements of the interbank leverage matrix along each of such cycles is larger than one (we refer to this as a combined unstable cycle). For instance, in the first example of Fig. 1, (Λ3)11 is larger than one for ω>2−1/3, and thus there is a range of values where the system is unstable even if the largest single exposure policy is implemented and the average interbank leverage is smaller than 1.
The sufficient condition for instability stated above has important consequences for regulations intended to promote financial stability. Take the case of a bank having a given interbank leverage and at least one exposure larger than its equity. If now the bank is required to implement the largest single exposure policy and it wants to keep its interbank leverage unchanged, it might have to increase the number of its counterparties. On the one hand, this is beneficial because it reduces the exposures towards individual counterparties. On the other hand, it might be detrimental as it could contribute to the creation of new cycles that, even though might be individually stable, are part of a combined unstable cycle. Therefore, a recommendation that targets stability in terms of individual banks can actually lead to instability because it neglects the systemic effect of cycles.
More in general, increasing the number of contracts in the system is the source of a second type of pathway towards instability. As an empirical illustration of this phenomenon, we consider the balance sheets of the top 50 listed banks in the European Union obtained from the Bankscope data set. We simulate a process in which banks gradually increase the degree of risk diversification by gradually creating exposures towards additional counterparties. We start from an interbank network whose topology is a DAG, which is stable. Exposures are assigned using the RAS algorithm45, which ensures that exposures are consistent with balance sheets, that is, that the total interbank assets and the total interbank liabilities of each bank are equal to the values reported in their balance sheets. We then create a new interbank exposure by randomly adding one edge to the graph. After the new edge has been added, interbank exposures are redistributed using the RAS algorithm so that the network is always consistent with the original balance sheets and interbank leverages of all banks do not change. Hence, even though the total amount of interbank exposures of each bank remains constant, as the networks grows denser such exposures are spread across more and more counterparties. As a consequence, the degree of diversification progressively increases. By iterating the steps above we build trajectories in the space of interbank networks whose initial configuration is a random DAG (hence stable) and whose final configuration is a complete graph. We find that, not only the banking system is unstable in this final configuration (that is, once its graph is complete), but actually that the instability kicks in much earlier, when the fraction of existing contracts over all the possible ones is as low as 3% (see Fig. 2 for 2013 balance sheets, and Supplementary Fig. 5 for other years). Moreover, from Fig. 2 we see that trajectories of λmax cannot be monotonic and that the critical line can be crossed multiple times, meaning that the system sways between stability and instability, before finally settling into an unstable state. We note that, while the definition of pathways towards instability requires the average interbank leverage to be constant, along the trajectories displayed in Fig. 2 all interbank leverages are constant. Therefore, the transitions from stability to instability should be interpreted in an even stronger sense.
In Fig. 3 we provide a stylized example that helps to connect such changes in the stability of the system to changes in the topology of the network. We start from a DAG, initially setting all non-zero elements of the interbank leverage matrix equal to w. We then add one edge at a time, always distributing the interbank leverage of each bank uniformly among the neighbouring (borrowing) banks. λmax increases every time a new cycle appears in the system. In contrast, λmax decreases whenever a new edge does not lead to the appearance of a new cycle. Intuitively, this behaviour can be explained in the following way. On the one hand, whenever a new cycle appears the possibility for the system to amplify shocks increases. On the other hand, whenever the addition of a new edge does not lead to the creation of a new cycle, the weights of those edges that are part of existing cycles become smaller because interbank leverages are constantly re-balanced, decreasing the ability of those cycles to amplify shocks.
Discussion
By providing a simple and rigorous mathematical explanation of how network effects arise, our results shed new light on the tension between the two main approaches to financial stability: the so-called microprudential one, focused on ensuring the stability of individual banks, and the macroprudential ones, targeted to the stability of the whole financial system.
We provide examples of sufficient conditions for the onset of instability: when banks establish contracts among each other without taking into account what their counterparties do, they will eventually become even unintentionally part of multiple cycles of contracts, which altogether amplify the effects of shocks. The recovery rate plays an important role, as it impacts directly the critical value of the largest eigenvalue. In turn, the recovery rate can be at least in part controlled with certain financial and monetary policies since it depends on both the quality of the collateral (in the case of secured lending) and on the liquidity of the asset markets. Overall, our findings suggest that financial stability policies need to carefully consider network effects. This can be achieved by computing the largest eigenvalue of the interbank leverage matrix and by comparing it with estimates of the recovery rate.
More specifically, we show the existence of two processes that define trajectories in the space of network configurations which drive financial networks from a stable to an unstable regime. The former consists of implementing processes of market integration (that is, increasing the number of financial institutions) in a growing interbank network with interbank leverage larger than one. The latter consists of increasing the number of contracts among financial institutions. In both cases the risk profile of individual banks (measured by the interbank leverage) does not change, and therefore the emergence of instability is purely related to the structure of the network. This suggests that policies targeted at ensuring financial stability by lowering the risk of individual banks without taking into account the network effects can in fact lead to a higher systemic risk.
Currently the stability of the financial system is assessed by regulatory authorities through stress tests, which are long procedures that last months and are typically run once per year. Stress tests are based on detailed econometric models that require a large number of inputs and the continued cooperation of banks. Even though increasingly sophisticated, usually stress tests consider financial institutions as isolated and neglect the consequences of distress propagation across the network of contracts established among them. Our approach is much more agile, as it allows to gauge the stability of the financial system only through the knowledge of the matrix . The information required to construct such matrix is: mutual exposures between banks (which regulatory authorities often have access to), equities (which are public) and recovery rates. Recovery rates are not directly measurable, but can be estimated47. Moreover, since the largest eigenvalue of the matrix is quickly computed, regulatory authorities can easily analyse a plurality of scenarios corresponding to different potential recovery rates. Finally, while our framework is currently focused on distress propagation due to mark-to-market revaluation of contracts, it is suitable for extensions to additional channels of contagion, such as liquidity shortage due to funds withdrawal. In this case, on the layer corresponding to deterioration of interbank assets the contagion would proceed from borrowers to lenders; on the layer corresponding to liquidity shortages it would proceed from lenders to borrowers. Typically, since relationships between banks might differ from channel to channel, one would construct a multilayered network48 with as many layers as the number of channels of contagion. All the layers would be coupled by a single dynamics whose stability could be studied. However, multi-layered networks often exhibit less resilience than single-layered networks32,49; therefore, as more contagion channels are taken into account, we expect the system to transition more easily to the unstable regime.
Data availability
All the relevant data are available from the authors on request. Raw data for banks’ balance sheet data come from the Bureau van Dijk Bankscope’s database.
Additional information
How to cite this article: Bardoscia, M. et al. Pathways towards instability in financial networks. Nat. Commun. 8, 14416 doi: 10.1038/ncomms14416 (2017).
Publisher’s note: Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
References
May, R. M. Will a large complex system be stable? Nature 238, 413–414 (1972).
Haldane, A. G. & May, R. M. Systemic risk in banking ecosystems. Nature 469, 351–355 (2011).
Schweitzer, F. et al. Economic networks: the new challenges. Science 325, 422–425 (2009).
Stiglitz, J. E. Risk and global economic architecture: why full financial integration may be undesirable. Am. Econ. Rev. 100, 388–392 (2010).
Brock, W. A., Hommes, C. H. & Wagener, F. O. O. More hedging instruments may destabilize markets. J. Econ. Dynam. Control 33, 1912–1928 (2009).
Battiston, S., Gatti, D. D., Gallegati, M., Greenwald, B. C. N. & Stiglitz, J. E. Liaisons dangereuses: increasing connectivity, risk sharing, and systemic risk. J. Econ. Dynam. Control 36, 1121–1141 (2012).
Arinaminpathy, N., Kapadia, S. & May, R. M. Size and complexity in model financial systems. Proc. Natl Acad. Sci. USA 109, 18338–18343 (2012).
Amini, H., Cont, R. & Minca, A. Stress testing the resilience of financial networks. Int. J. Theoret. Appl. Finance 15, 1250006 (2012).
Gai, P. & Kapadia, S. Contagion in financial networks. Proc. R. Soc. A 466, 2401–2423 (2010).
Dehmamy, N., Buldyrev, S. V., Havlin, S., Stanley, H. E. & Vodenska, I. Classical mechanics of economic networks. Preprint at http://arxiv.org/abs/1410.0104 (2014).
Battiston, S., Puliga, M., Kaushik, R., Tasca, P. & Caldarelli, G. DebtRank: too central to fail? financial networks, the FED and systemic risk. Sci. Rep. 2, 541 (2012).
Montagna, M. & Lux, T. Contagion risk in the interbank market: a probabilistic approach to cope with incomplete structural information. Quantitative Finance 17, 101–120 (2017).
Battiston, S., Caldarelli, G., D’Errico, M. & Gurciullo, S. Leveraging the network: a stress-test framework based on DebtRank. Statist. Risk Model 33, 117–138 (2016).
Bardoscia, M., Battiston, S., Caccioli, F. & Caldarelli, G. DebtRank: a microscopic foundation for shock propagation. PLoS ONE 10, e0134888 (2015).
Levy-Carciente, S., Kenett, D. Y., Avakian, A., Stanley, H. E. & Havlin, S. Dynamical macroprudential stress testing using network theory. J. Bank. Finance 59, 164–181 (2015).
Markose, S., Giansante, S. & Shaghaghi, A. R. ‘Too interconnected to fail’ financial network of US CDS market: topological fragility and systemic risk. J. Econ. Behav. Org. 83, 627–646 (2012).
Caccioli, F., Shrestha, M., Moore, C. & Doyne Farmer, J. Stability analysis of financial contagion due to overlapping portfolios. J. Bank. Finance 46, 233–245 (2014).
Elsinger, H., Lehar, A. & Summer, M. Risk assessment for banking systems. Manage. Sci. 52, 1301–1314 (2006).
Thurner, S., Farmer, J. D. & Geanakoplos, J. Leverage causes fat tails and clustered volatility. Quant. Finance 12, 695–707 (2012).
Allen, F. & Gale, D. Financial contagion. J. polit. econ. 108, 1–33 (2000).
Acemoglu, D., Ozdaglar, A. & Tahbaz-Salehi, A. Systemic risk and stability in financial networks. Am. Econ. Rev. 105, 564–608 (2015).
Elliott, M., Golub, B. & Jackson, M. O. Financial networks and contagion. Am. Econ. Rev. 104, 3115–3153 (2014).
Corsi, F., Marmi, S. & Lillo, F. When micro prudence increases macro risk: the destabilizing effects of financial innovation, leverage, and diversification. Oper. Res. 64, 1073–1088 (2016).
Battiston, S. et al. Complexity theory to support public policy and financial regulation. Science 351, 818–819 (2016).
Gai, P., Haldane, A. & Kapadia, S. Complexity, concentration and contagion. J Monetary Econ. 58, 453–470 (2011).
Anand, K., Gai, P. & Marsili, M. Rollover risk, network structure and systemic financial crises. J. Econ. Dynam. Control 36, 1088–1100 (2012).
Eisenberg, L. & Noe, T. H. Systemic risk in financial systems. Manage. Sci. 47, 236–249 (2001).
Furfine, C. H. Interbank exposures: quantifying the risk of contagion. J.Money, Credit Bank. 35, 111–129 (2003).
Glasserman, P. & Young, H. P. How likely is contagion in financial networks. J. Bank. Finance 50, 383–399 (2015).
Battiston, S., D’Errico, M. & Visentin, G. Rethinking financial contagion. Preprint at http://ssrn.com/abstract=2831143 (2016).
Kiyotaki, N. & Moore, J. Balance-sheet contagion. Am. Econ. Rev. 92, 46–50 (2002).
Caccioli, F., Farmer, J. D., Foti, N. & Rockmore, D. Overlapping portfolios, contagion, and financial stability. J. Econ. Dynam. Control 51, 50–63 (2015).
Thurner, S. & Poledna, S. DebtRank-transparency: controlling systemic risk in financial networks. Scient. Rep. 3, 1888 (2013).
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. Basel III: a global regulatory framework for more resilient banks and banking systems. Available at http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs189.pdf (2011).
Bollobás, B. Random Graphs Cambridge University Press (2001).
Financial Stability Board. Update of list of global systemically important banks. Available at http://www.fsb.org/wp-content/uploads/r_141106b.pdf (2014).
Borgatti, S. P. & Everett, M. G. Models of core/periphery structures. Social Networks 21, 375–395 (2000).
Barabási, A.-L. Scale-free networks: a decade and beyond. Science 325, 412–413 (2009).
Shai, S. et al. Critical tipping point distinguishing two types of transitions in modular network structures. Phys. Rev. E 92, 062805 (2015).
Craig, B. & Von Peter, G. Interbank tiering and money center banks. J. Financ. Intermed. 23, 322–347 (2014).
Fricke, D. & Lux, T. Core-periphery structure in the overnight money market: evidence from the e-mid trading platform. Comput. Econ. 45, 359–395 (2015).
Anand, K., Craig, B. & Von Peter, G. Filling in the blanks: network structure and interbank contagion. Quant. Finance 15, 625–636 (2015).
Cimini, G., Squartini, T., Garlaschelli, D. & Gabrielli, A. Systemic risk analysis in reconstructed economic and financial networks. Sci. Rep. 5, 15758 (2016).
Mastrandrea, R., Squartini, T., Fagiolo, G. & Garlaschelli, D. Enhanced reconstruction of weighted networks from strengths and degrees. N. J. Phys. 16, 043022 (2014).
Upper, C. & Worms, A. Estimating bilateral exposures in the german interbank market: is there a danger of contagion? Eur. Econ. Rev. 48, 827–849 (2004).
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. Supervisory framework for measuring and controlling large exposures. Available at http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs283.pdf (2014).
Altman, E. I., Brady, B., Resti, A. & Sironi, A. The link between default and recovery rates: theory, empirical evidence, and implications. J. Bus. 78, 2203 (2005).
Bookstaber, R. & Kenett, D. Y. Looking deeper, seeing more: a multilayer map of the financial system. Available at https://financialresearch.gov/briefs/2016/07/14/multilayer-map (2016).
Buldyrev, S. V., Parshani, R., Paul, G., Stanley, H. E. & Havlin, S. Catastrophic cascade of failures in interdependent networks. Nature 464, 1025–1028 (2010).
Acknowledgements
We are grateful to Joseph E. Stiglitz and Mark Buchanan for their comments on the manuscript. We also acknowledge Marco D’Errico for the discussions on the notion of interbank leverage and for sharing the banks’ balance sheet data used in the empirical applications. M.B., S.B. and G.C. acknowledge support from: FET Project SIMPOL nr. 610704, FET Project DOLFINS nr. 640772 and FET IP Project MULTIPLEX nr. 317532. F.C. acknowledges support of the Economic and Social Research Council (ESRC) in funding the Systemic Risk Centre (ES/K002309/1). S.B. acknowledges the Swiss National Fund Professorship grant nr. PP00P1-144689. G.C. acknowledges also EU projects SoBigData nr. 654024 and CoeGSS nr. 676547.
Author information
Authors and Affiliations
Contributions
All authors contributed to all aspects of this work.
Corresponding author
Ethics declarations
Competing interests
The authors declare no competing financial interests.
Supplementary information
Supplementary Methods
Supplementary Methods, Supplementary Figures, Supplementary References (PDF 1091 kb)
Rights and permissions
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in the credit line; if the material is not included under the Creative Commons license, users will need to obtain permission from the license holder to reproduce the material. To view a copy of this license, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/
About this article
Cite this article
Bardoscia, M., Battiston, S., Caccioli, F. et al. Pathways towards instability in financial networks. Nat Commun 8, 14416 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1038/ncomms14416
Received:
Accepted:
Published:
DOI: https://doi.org/10.1038/ncomms14416
This article is cited by
-
Contingent convertible bonds in financial networks
Scientific Reports (2023)
-
Detecting the socio-economic drivers of confidence in government with eXplainable Artificial Intelligence
Scientific Reports (2023)
-
Early warning of systemic risk in global banking: eigen-pair R number for financial contagion and market price-based methods
Annals of Operations Research (2023)
-
A dynamic network model to measure exposure concentration in the Austrian interbank market
Statistical Methods & Applications (2023)
-
On the fragility of the Italian economic territories under SARS-COV2 lockdown policies
Annals of Operations Research (2023)
Comments
By submitting a comment you agree to abide by our Terms and Community Guidelines. If you find something abusive or that does not comply with our terms or guidelines please flag it as inappropriate.