Skip to main content

Thank you for visiting nature.com. You are using a browser version with limited support for CSS. To obtain the best experience, we recommend you use a more up to date browser (or turn off compatibility mode in Internet Explorer). In the meantime, to ensure continued support, we are displaying the site without styles and JavaScript.

  • Article
  • Published:

The growth equation of cities

Abstract

The science of cities seeks to understand and explain regularities observed in the world’s major urban systems. Modelling the population evolution of cities is at the core of this science and of all urban studies. Quantitatively, the most fundamental problem is to understand the hierarchical organization of city population and the statistical occurrence of megacities. This was first thought to be described by a universal principle known as Zipf’s law1,2; however, the validity of this model has been challenged by recent empirical studies3,4. A theoretical model must also be able to explain the relatively frequent rises and falls of cities and civilizations5, but despite many attempts6,7,8,9,10 these fundamental questions have not yet been satisfactorily answered. Here we introduce a stochastic equation for modelling population growth in cities, constructed from an empirical analysis of recent datasets (for Canada, France, the UK and the USA). This model reveals how rare, but large, interurban migratory shocks dominate city growth. This equation predicts a complex shape for the distribution of city populations and shows that, owing to finite-time effects, Zipf’s law does not hold in general, implying a more complex organization of cities. It also predicts the existence of multiple temporal variations in the city hierarchy, in agreement with observations5. Our result underlines the importance of rare events in the evolution of complex systems11 and, at a more practical level, in urban planning.

This is a preview of subscription content, access via your institution

Access options

Buy this article

Prices may be subject to local taxes which are calculated during checkout

Fig. 1: Migration flow analysis.
Fig. 2: Rank clocks for France.

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

The datasets used in this study are freely available from public repositories43,44,45,46.

References

  1. Zipf, G. K. Human Behavior and the Principle of Least Effort (Addison-Wesley, 1949).

  2. Auerbach, F. Das Gesetz der Bevölkerungskonzentration. Petermanns Geogr. Mitt. 59, 74–76 (1913).

    Google Scholar 

  3. Arshad, S., Hu, S. & Ashraf, B. N. Zipf’s law and city size distribution: a survey of the literature and future research agenda. Physica A 492, 75–92 (2018).

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  4. Gan, L., Li, D. & Song, S. Is the Zipf law spurious in explaining city-size distributions? Econ. Lett. 92, 256–262 (2006).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Batty, M. Rank clocks. Nature 444, 592–596 (2006).

    Article  ADS  CAS  Google Scholar 

  6. Duranton, G. & Puga, D. in Handbook of Economic Growth Vol. 2 (eds Aghion, P. & Durlauf, S.) 781–853 (Elsevier, 2014).

  7. Córdoba, J.-C. On the distribution of city sizes. J. Urban Econ. 63, 177–197 (2008).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  8. Rossi-Hansberg, E. & Wright, M. Urban structure and growth. Rev. Econ. Stud. 74, 597–624 (2007).

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  9. Gibrat, R. Les inégalités économiques (Librairie du Recueil Sierey, 1931).

  10. Gabaix, X. Zipf’s law for cities: an explanation. Q. J. Econ. 114, 739–767 (1999).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. Bouchaud, J.-P. Crises and collective socio-economic phenomena: simple models and challenges. J. Stat. Phys. 151, 567–606 (2013).

    Article  ADS  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  12. Bettencourt, L. & West, G. A unified theory of urban living. Nature 467, 912–913 (2010).

    Article  ADS  CAS  Google Scholar 

  13. Soo, K. T. Zipf’s law for cities: a cross-country investigation. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 35, 239–263 (2005).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  14. Singer, H. The “Courbe des populations”. A parallel to Pareto’s law. Econ. J. 46, 254–263 (1936).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Gabaix, X., Lasry, J. M., Lions, P. L. & Moll, B. The dynamics of inequality. Econometrica 84, 2071–2111 (2016).

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  16. Pumain, D. & Moriconi-Ebrard, F. City size distributions and metropolisation. GeoJournal 43, 307–314 (1997).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Barthelemy, M. The Structure and Dynamics of Cities (Cambridge Univ. Press, 2016).

  18. Corominas-Murtra, B. & Solé, R. Universality of Zipf’s law. Phys. Rev. E 82, 011102 (2010).

    Article  ADS  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  19. Pumain, D. Une théorie géographique pour la loi de Zipf. Reg. Dév. 36, 125–150 (2012).

    Google Scholar 

  20. Marsili, M. & Zhang, Y.-C. Interacting individuals leading to Zipf’s law. Phys. Rev. Lett. 80, 2741–2744 (1998).

    Article  ADS  CAS  Google Scholar 

  21. Cottineau, C. MetaZipf. A dynamic meta-analysis of city size distributions. PLoS One 12, e0183919 (2017).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  22. Benguigui, L. & Blumenfeld-Lieberthal, E. A dynamic model for city size distribution beyond Zipf’s law. Physica A 384, 613–627 (2007).

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  23. Blank, A. & Solomon, S. Power laws in cities population, financial markets and internet sites (scaling in systems with a variable number of components). Physica A 287, 279–288 (2000).

    Article  ADS  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  24. Krugman, P. Confronting the mystery of urban hierarchy. J. Jpn. Int. Econ. 10, 399–418 (1996).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Ioannides, Y. & Overman, H. Zipf’s law for cities: an empirical examination. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 33, 127–137 (2003).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Favaro, J. M. & Pumain, D. Gibrat revisited: an urban growth model incorporating spatial interaction and innovation cycles. Geogr. Anal. 43, 261–286 (2011).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  27. Zanette, D. H. & Manrubia, S. C. Role of intermittency in urban development: a model of large-scale city formation. Phys. Rev. Lett. 79, 523–526 (1997).

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  28. Cottineau, C., Reuillon, R., Chapron, P., Rey-Coyrehourcq, S. & Pumain, D. A modular modelling framework for hypotheses testing in the simulation of urbanisation. Systems 3, 348–377 (2015).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  29. Bettencourt, L. & Zünd, D. Demography, symmetry and the emergence of universal patterns in urban systems. Nat. Commun. 11, 19 (2020).

  30. Black, D. & Henderson, V. Urban evolution in the USA. J. Econ. Geogr. 3, 343–372 (2003).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  31. Eeckhout, J. Gibrat’s law for (all) cities. Am. Econ. Rev. 94, 1429–1451 (2004).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Benguigui, L. & Blumenfeld-Lieberthal, E. The end of a paradigm: is Zipf’s law universal? J. Geogr. Syst. 13, 87–100 (2011).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Bouchaud, J. P. & Mézard, M. Wealth condensation in a simple model of economy. Physica A 282, 536–545 (2000).

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  34. Erlander, S. & Stewart, N. F. The Gravity Model in Transportation Analysis: Theory and Extensions (VSP, 1990).

  35. Simini, F., Gonzalez, M. C., Maritan A. & Barabasi, A.-L. A universal model for mobility and migration patterns. Nature 484, 96–100 (2012).

    Article  ADS  CAS  Google Scholar 

  36. Gnedenko, B. V. & Kolmogorov, A. N. Limit Distributions for Sums of Independent Random Variables (Addison-Wesley, 1954).

  37. van Kampen, N. G. Itô versus Stratonovich. J. Stat. Phys. 24, 175–187 (1981).

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  38. Srokowski, T. Multiplicative Lévy processes: Itô versus Stratonovich interpretation. Phys. Rev. E 80, 051113 (2009).

    Article  ADS  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  39. Jespersen, S. M. R. & Fogedby, H. C. Lévy flights in external force fields: Langevin and fractional Fokker–Planck equations and their solutions. Phys. Rev. E 59, 2736–2745 (1999).

    Article  ADS  CAS  Google Scholar 

  40. Schertzer, D., Larchevêque, M., Duan, J., Yanovsky, V. & Lovejoy, S. Fractional Fokker–Planck equation for nonlinear stochastic differential equations driven by non-Gaussian Lévy stable noises. J. Math. Phys. 42, 200–212 (2001).

    Article  ADS  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  41. Fox, C. The G and H functions as symmetrical Fourier kernels. Trans. Am. Math. Soc. 98, 395–429 (1961).

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  42. Clauset, A., Shalizi, C. R. & Newman, M. E. Power-law distributions in empirical data. SIAM Rev. 51, 661–703 (2009).

    Article  ADS  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  43. United States Census Bureau. Metro area-to-metro area migration flows: 2013–2017 American Community Survey; https://www.census.gov/data/tables/2017/demo/geographic-mobility/metro-to-metro-migration.html (United States Census Bureau, 2019).

  44. INSEE. Migrations résidentielles en 2008: lieu de résidence actuelle – lieu de résidence antérieure; https://www.insee.fr/fr/statistiques/2022291 (INSEE, 2011).

  45. Park, N. Internal migration: matrices of moves by local authority and region (countries of the UK) 2012–2016; https://www.ons.gov.uk/peoplepopulationandcommunity/populationandmigration/migrationwithintheuk/datasets/matricesofinternalmigrationmovesbetweenlocalauthoritiesandregionsincludingthecountriesofwalesscotlandandnorthernireland (Office for National Statistics, 2019).

  46. Statistics Canada. Interprovincial and intraprovincial migrants, by census metropolitan area of origin and destination for the period from July 1 to June 30; https://doi.org/10.25318/1710008701-eng (Statistics Canada, 2020).

Download references

Acknowledgements

V.V. is supported by the Ecole nationale des ponts et chaussées and by the Complex Systems Institute of Paris Île-de-France (ISC-PIF). V.V. thanks J. Morán for discussions and comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

V.V. and M.B. designed the study, V.V. acquired the data, and V.V. and M.B. analysed and interpreted the data and wrote the manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marc Barthelemy.

Ethics declarations

Competing interests

The authors declare no competing interests.

Additional information

Peer review information Nature thanks Amos Maritan and the other, anonymous, reviewer(s) for their contribution to the peer review of this work.

Publisher’s note Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Extended data figures and tables

Extended Data Fig. 1 No universal exponent.

We show here the measured Pareto exponent of the upper tail of city-size distributions as a function of the lower threshold defining the tail for the largest cities of eight different countries. The exponents are obtained with a maximum-likelihood estimate (data from https://simplemaps.com/data/world-cities).

Extended Data Fig. 2 In- and out-neighbours.

a, b, Number of in- and out-neighbours (in the sense of graph theory) for the USA (a) and France (b). The red lines correspond to the equality Nin = Nout. In the UK and Canada, we have a fully connected dataset and Nin = Nout = constant. cd, Number of neighbours for each city as a function of population for the USA (c) and France (d). The dotted red lines indicate the power-law fit |Ni| \({S}_{i}^{\gamma }\). In the UK and Canada, we have a variance of the normalized quantity fully connected dataset and γ = 0.

Extended Data Fig. 3 Density function of the out-of-system growth rate.

Natural growth and out-of-system migrations include international migrations and exchanges with small towns. The data shown are for US cities in 2013–2017 (top) and French cities (bottom) in 2003–2008, compared to a normal distribution. We note that a power-law fit of the right or the left tail would lead to a Pareto exponent of β 1. For French cities, we extrapolated the 2003 population in each city from the 1999 and 2006 censuses to test our assumption on the period 2003–2008.

Extended Data Fig. 4 Migration-flow analysis.

Complementary figure to Fig. 2. Empirical left-cumulative distribution function of renormalized migration flows compared to Lévy (continuous red line) and normal (green dashed lines) distributions. Clockwise from top left, distributions are given for France, the USA, Canada and the UK.

Extended Data Fig. 5 Average distribution of city sizes.

Data obtained by 10 numerical runs of the stochastic differential equation (10) with a Gaussian noise with finite variance ση, compared with the numerical solution of equation (10) where η = η = r. Parameters here are α = 1.3, β = 0.8, r = 0.01, ση = 0.06, D = 0.06 and t = 500.

Extended Data Fig. 6 Scatterplot of the quantity P(St) × S versus the ratio for France’s top-500 largest cities between 1875 and 2016.

Each colour is a different year. We observe that the plots of all years collapse towards a unique universal function of the ratio in agreement with the result of equation (33) in Supplementary Information.

Extended Data Fig. 7 Power-law fit of the expansion with α = 1.3, as a function of the lower threshold of city sizes, Smin.

The expansion is described in equation (25) in Supplementary Information. The fit gives an apparent exponent α(Smin) with very good quality (R2 ≈ 1), although the expansion itself is not a power law. The apparent exponent is smaller than α, but slowly converges towards α = 1.3 as the value of the threshold Smin increases. Parameters here are α = 1.3, β = 0.8, r = 0.01, D = 0.06 and t = 500.

Extended Data Fig. 8 Rank clocks of the USA and the UK.

Top, USA; bottom, UK. The left panels display real data, the middle panels show Gabaix’s model of growth and the right panels give our model of growth. Parallel lines for earlier years are spurious effects resulting from the absence of data for cities out of the top-100 largest in the USA or the top-40 largest in the UK (for these rank clocks, we assigned a random increasing radius to cities without data).

Extended Data Fig. 9 Microdynamics of city rank through time for the largest cities in France, the USA and the UK.

Data is given for the 500 largest cities in France between 1875 and 2016 (top), the 100 largest cities in the United States between 1790 and 1990 (middle) and the 40 largest cities in the UK between 1861 and 1991 (bottom). The left panels display the right-cumulative distribution of the maximal variation of the rank ri(t) for city, that is, the difference between the highest and the lowest rank in population for each city. The right panels display the typical fluctuations of the rank ri(t) through time. In the three cases, the Lévy model is able to predict rare but non-negligible large variations of rank such as the sudden birth or death of city, in contrast to Gabaix’s model or Gibrat’s model for growth, for which large fluctuations of rank order do not occur.

Extended Data Fig. 10 Average number of years (and standard dispersion) taken to observe the maximal rank variation ∆r as a function of ∆r.

Although the dispersion is large, Lévy’s model is compatible with real data, in contrast to Gabaix’s model of growth.

Supplementary information

Supplementary Information

This file contains a Supplementary Discussion.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Verbavatz, V., Barthelemy, M. The growth equation of cities. Nature 587, 397–401 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1038/s41586-020-2900-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1038/s41586-020-2900-x

This article is cited by

Comments

By submitting a comment you agree to abide by our Terms and Community Guidelines. If you find something abusive or that does not comply with our terms or guidelines please flag it as inappropriate.

Search

Quick links

Nature Briefing

Sign up for the Nature Briefing newsletter — what matters in science, free to your inbox daily.

Get the most important science stories of the day, free in your inbox. Sign up for Nature Briefing