Main

In the Paris Agreement, adopted in 2015, countries agreed to hold global mean temperature rise to well below 2 °C while aiming to limit it to 1.5 °C. The scientific community has since focused its efforts on understanding what it would take for the world to meet this target1. Modellers have looked at requirements to meet the most stringent 1.5 °C ambition2, quantifying the necessary transformations3,4 and the consequences of living in a 2 °C rather than a 1.5 °C world5. Initial climate pledges in the context of Paris negotiations were soon found inadequate6 but, despite the slower-than-necessary pace7,8, countries have kept ramping up their ambition since. Several studies have quantified the actual impact of international policy efforts9,10,11, showcasing that ‘business-as-usual’ scenarios that are loosely defined and/or miss this impact of hitherto efforts are not helpful12,13, increasing pressure for better, more realistic analysis of where the world is heading14. A growing body of literature15,16,17, thus, shed light on what policies currently in place and what official 2030 Nationally Determined Contributions (NDCs) would yield, establishing their inadequacy to limit warming to 2 °C (refs. 18,19).

Although the critical climate talks of the 26th Conference of the Parties (COP26)—a milestone for ratcheting ambition—were delayed by a year due to COVID-19, parties followed up on their commitments; by the time COP26 was completed in Glasgow in November 2021, more than 120 countries had upgraded their 2030 targets20 and major emitters representing over 70% of global CO2 emissions had announced and/or adopted net-zero commitments21. A handful of studies attempted to quickly assess the outcome of these new promises22,23,24,25,26,27, showing that—if fully implemented—global climate ambition could hold global temperature rise to just below 2 °C by 2100. More efforts to comprehend the effect of the new generation of NDCs and long-term targets (LTTs) followed28,29. Nonetheless, each of these studies was based on a single model and, despite stagnation of such bold promises largely due to the current energy crisis30, a multimodel assessment of global climate pledges remains critical. Our study contributes to this research gap, aiming to enhance robustness and confidence in our knowledge of possible global warming outcomes, by exploiting a diverse ensemble of integrated assessment models (IAMs) and breaking down the climate action gap in an implementation gap (temperature difference between current policies and NDCs), a long-term ratchet gap (temperature difference between NDCs followed or not by LTTs) and a long-term ambition gap (difference between temperature achieved by LTTs and the 1.5 °C goal) (Fig. 1; ‘Climate action gap definition’ in Methods).

Fig. 1: Global overview of study design (fictional data points for graphical representation).
figure 1

The four IAMs applied are GCAM-PR, GEMINI-E3, MUSE and TIAM-Grantham. The climate emulator used is FaIR, with Silicone as infilling tool. See Methods for more details.

Model diversity also implies a plurality of modelling paradigms, theories, solution mechanisms and thus pathways that each model yields31. Given the political commitment to 1.5 °C—which was further strengthened in the Glasgow Climate Pact1—and the ambition reflected in announced net-zero pledges, special emphasis is increasingly placed on thresholds or boundaries that modelled pathways must stay within to be considered feasible32. According to the Sixth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC AR6), feasibility refers to the potential for a mitigation (or adaptation) option to be implemented, on the basis of diverse context-dependent factors33—including institutional, financial and political34,35,36. Conversely, from a modelling perspective, feasibility refers to quantifiable geophysical, environmental-ecological, technological, economic and even sociocultural factors37. Feasibility assessments hitherto referred to challenges at the global level38,39 and/or have been used to explicitly assess 1.5 °C-compliant pathways40, without touching upon regional feasibility concerns of decarbonization pathways required to achieve announced pledges. Our study builds on the multidimensional feasibility assessment framework established by ref. 38, to identify where and when the largest bottlenecks to achieving climate targets can be found, from a socioeconomic, technological and physical feasibility perspective (Fig. 1; ‘Feasibility assessment’ in Methods). However, a key novelty of our study lies in the expansion of the regional disaggregation of this framework, allowing us to assess to what extent and from which perspective countries’ policy targets, NDCs and LTTs are feasible.

Global action gap

We use three scenarios, each corresponding to a different level of climate action or stated ambition, as announced by June 2022 (Fig. 1): a scenario with current emissions reduction policies until 2030, with post-2030 extrapolation maintaining 2020–2030 emission intensity (EI) tendencies (‘Scenario protocol’ in Methods); a scenario with current NDC targets for 2030, with the same EI extrapolation; and a scenario with NDC targets until 2030 followed by LTTs.

To compare emissions between scenarios we focus on global CO2 emissions from energy and industrial processes to 2050 as all our IAMs represent these emissions sources as a minimum, while we include non-CO2 emissions and short-lived climate forcers in our temperature assessment (see below). When including all relevant national and regional energy and climate policies on top of socio- and technoeconomic baseline assumptions, we find that CO2 emissions will stabilize or start declining in the current decade, reaching 33–38 Gt by 2030 (Fig. 2). If policy effort is sufficiently strengthened to reach stated NDC targets, we find across models that emissions are reduced towards 2030, reaching 30–33 Gt. If all countries continue their declining trend in EI of gross domestic product (GDP) beyond 2030, global emissions will achieve levels of around 24–30 and 19–23 Gt by 2050—for current policies and NDCs, respectively. However, if countries accelerate action post-2030 to meet their long-term emission targets, we find 2050 emissions in the range of 10–13 Gt.

Fig. 2: Global fossil CO2 emissions and related temperature assessment.
figure 2

a, Global CO2 emissions from fossil fuel combustion. Historical emissions (black solid line) are taken from the Community Emmisions Data System (CEDS) database53. b, Temperature outcomes across the four models and three scenarios used in this study and the distribution of the climate action gap based on median temperatures. Temperature boxplots for all scenarios and models are derived from 2237 runs using the simple climate model FaIR (Methods). Triangles in temperature boxplots mark peak temperatures achieved before 2100. In scenarios without a triangle, 2100 temperatures are represented which are still on an increasing trend.

Source data

Model spread is largest for current policies, since models run largely in forecasting mode, simulating the impact of policies relative to a model-dependent no-policy baseline. Despite harmonization of many input assumptions to reduce unwanted response heterogeneity (‘Scenario protocol’ in Methods), no-policy baselines tend to differ strongly, driven by inherent model characteristics and remaining unharmonized inputs18. Therefore, despite the converging effect of modelling a common set of current energy and climate policies, model variation still tends to be large in such exercises14,41 (Table 1). Model spread for emissions substantially decreases when emission targets from NDCs and LTTs are used as absolute constraints. The remaining emission spread can be explained by a mix of factors, such as model regions overperforming their targets, differences in regional aggregation and the CO2 versus non-CO2 share in emissions reductions. While total emissions outcomes between models converge when applying constraints, the distributions of emissions over the different sectors diverge between the models, reflecting the heterogeneity of mitigation pathways preferred by each model (Extended Data Fig. 1).

Table 1 Model key characteristics and mapping of characteristics to major feasibility concerns

Although temperature outcomes depend on all CO2 emissions (energy, industrial processes and land use), the remaining Kyoto gases (CH4, N2O and fluorinated gases) and short-lived climate forcers (SO2, black and organic carbon and so on), most of our models only cover a subset of those (Table 1). Therefore, we estimate the temperature implications of our scenarios after infilling missing GHGs and climate forcers, harmonizing the emission data and running the emission outcomes through the simple climate model FaIR (‘Temperature assessment’ in Methods). We find that current ambition levels signalled through implemented energy and climate policies will increase global temperatures to 2.1–2.4 °C above pre-industrial levels by 2100, depending on the model (1.9–2.7 °C when including climate uncertainty at the 25–75% interval), while ambition levels stated in present NDCs slightly limit this increase to 2.0–2.2 °C (1.7–2.5 °C for 25–75% interval). In both cases, warming will continue after 2100, as global CO2 emissions will not yet have reached net-zero levels. If countries also comply with their stated LTTs after meeting their current NDC pledges in 2030, temperature increase will be further limited and stabilize around 1.7–1.8 °C (1.5–2.0 °C for 25–75% interval), which is arguably in line with a future ‘well below 2 °C’ (ref. 42). Depending on the model applied, this translates to an implementation gap of 0.1–0.4 °C additional warming on the one hand and a long-term ratchet gap equivalent to another 0.2–0.5 °C of warming on the other. The remaining global ambition gap compared to the Paris target of keeping global temperature increase to 1.5 °C would be around 0.2–0.3 °C for all models. For three out of four models (General Equilibrium Model of International–National Interactions between Economy, Energy and the Environment (GEMINI), Modular energy systems Simulation Environment (MUSE) and Times Integrated Assessment Model (TIAM)), the long-term ratchet gap contributes most to the entire climate action gap. This confirms previous assessments showing that mitigation in current NDCs is not aligned with LTTs for most countries24,28. For the Global Change Analysis Model (GCAM), the implementation gap contributes most to the entire gap, instead.

Disaggregating the emission results for the six largest emitters (Fig. 4) shows where the different gaps are more relevant. The implementation gap is measured to be largest (in relative terms) for the US and Japan, which have relatively ambitious NDCs but their policies are lagging behind. For countries with relatively less ambitious NDCs, like China, India and Russia, the implementation gap is smaller or non-existent, as existing policies overachieve NDC targets in several cases. In the European Union (EU), the implementation gap is relatively small due to ambitious policies. The long-term ratchet gap is substantial for all cases, meaning that, with current NDC targets, all six regions require a notable boost in post-2030 climate action for their net-zero targets to be achievable. However, differences between models are non-negligible, as GCAM shows an implementation gap in all countries, except Russia, while GEMINI does only for the US. Driven largely by announced emissions targets, pathways towards LTTs are relatively similar between the models, except India and Russia, due to different modelled or assumed contributions from non-CO2 emissions and natural sinks towards net-zero targets. We have not assessed the ambition gap at the country level, as that would require an assessment of fairness and equity43.

Scenario feasibility

The feasibility of the modelled scenarios based on national policies and targets is measured by comparing specific scenario outcomes with predetermined thresholds (Supplementary Section 2). Surpassing a threshold indicates that the feasibility of achievement in that dimension might become concerning. Global results show that feasibility concerns vary strongly between models, between scenarios and over time (Fig. 3a). Logically, deeper mitigation efforts imply larger feasibility concerns, as they drive models further away from their emissions-unconstrained baselines. Achieving stated LTTs among all countries—the only option of keeping temperature increase well below 2 °C (Fig. 2)—implies that regional feasibility thresholds must be passed three-to-six times (global weighted average and with median thresholds), depending on the model, and aggregated over the different feasibility dimensions. The feasibility metrics are only based on mitigation and do not consider the adaptation challenges that are driven by lack of mitigation. In fact, the feasibility of adequate adaptation to make up for lack of mitigation may be substantially more concerning—that is, in terms of costs, pace of investment scale-up and land and freshwater availability44,45—but this is outside the scope of this study. These feasibility concerns can, therefore, be best understood as key aspects requiring attention for successful implementation of the ambitious mitigation policies.

Fig. 3: Globally averaged feasibility concerns of all scenarios by feasibility indicator.
figure 3

a, The concerns for the set of chosen feasibility thresholds in this study (Methods). b, The sensitivity of feasibility concerns to the chosen threshold level. For all indicators, a concern value of 1 represents that the specific threshold for that indicator is surpassed by 100% in that specific model region and period. Similarly, scores of 0.5 and 1.5 mean surpassing the thresholds by, respectively, 50% and 150%. As long as the threshold is not passed, even if it comes close, the feasibility concern is measured as zero. Similarly for all indicators, the global value is built up as a weighted average of the independent values in all model regions. See Table 2, Methods and Supplementary Section 3 for further details.

Source data

Since the models differ substantially in structure, resulting in a wide variety of mitigation pathways, this also translates to large variations in the level and timing of feasibility concerns between the four models (Table 1), with GEMINI showing the lowest concerns and MUSE the highest. However, the distribution of feasibility concerns over the different dimensions and over time are crucial for the interpretation. For example, the high overall concern for MUSE is largely driven by high carbon prices and demand reduction pathways. In contrast, these dimensions are hardly of concern for GCAM and TIAM, where the pace of technology deployment and—in the case of GCAM—reliance on bioenergy and CCS are the main sources of feasibility concern. When evaluating feasibility concerns over time, all three TIAM scenarios stand out for showing most near-term concerns, predominantly related to the high pace of wind and solar energy deployment to deliver on 2030 targets. In GCAM, feasibility concerns are relatively small in the run-up to 2030 but arise in later periods, largely driven by increasing reliance on bioenergy with carbon capture and storage (BECCS). The latter is concerning from three different feasibility perspectives, pace of technology deployment, availability of sustainable bioenergy resources and geological carbon storage capacity.

Mitigation scenarios in this study are entirely driven by country-specific climate policies and ambitions, hence we also specify an overview of measured feasibility concerns for the six largest emitters, averaged over 2020–2050 (Fig. 4). While again large differences between models exist, overall, we see relatively low concerns in China and Russia and high concerns in the US, the EU and Japan. These differences are probably driven by more ambitious targets in the latter group, which—despite being already in an emissions reduction phase for at least a decade—still confront high feasibility constraints to meet their near- and longer-term targets. Specific feasibility issues that stand out include energy demand reductions in the US (GEMINI), carbon pricing in the EU (MUSE) and bioenergy and carbon storage potentials for Japan (GCAM). Feasibility concerns about the pace of technology deployment play a relatively small role in China, the US and the EU, as opposed to India, Russia and Japan.

Fig. 4: Emissions pathways and feasibility analysis for six largest emitters, across all four models and three scenarios in this study.
figure 4

Historical emissions (black solid lines) are taken from CEDS database53. See Fig. 3, Table 2 and Methods for more details on feasibility measurement.

Source data

The interpretation of the measured feasibility concerns can be subjective. The predetermined thresholds are not set in stone and often large ranges for such thresholds exist in literature38,39, while threshold levels strongly affect measured feasibility concerns—as showcased in a sensitivity analysis illustrating the impact of threshold uncertainty on feasibility concern values (Fig. 3b). Experts in different fields may have very different views on what is feasible or not. At the same time, our definition of feasibility is defined by ten indicators, as constrained by our modelling capacity (Table 2; ‘Feasibility assessment’ section in Methods); including other indicators in the analysis might have highlighted different dimensions and affected overall (aggregate) feasibility levels. Also, country-specific features, such as country size, stage of development, economic structure or access to international financial markets, would influence the threshold level. While some of these features are weighted in the feasibility assessment (for example, the thresholds for carbon pricing depend on GDP per capita levels), not all can be considered (for example, economic structure). Moreover, our feasibility assessment only applies to the underlying socioeconomic ‘storyline’ provided in the scenario protocol (‘Scenario protocol’ in Methods). Emissions associated with our pathways, largely constrained by 2030 NDCs and net-zero targets, are not subject to wide variation across storylines, as the latter would be without emissions constraints46 (noting that, for India and China, the emissions-intensity-based NDCs will vary according to their projected economic growth). However, existing analysis shows that key feasibility-related indicators of 1.5 °C pathways—including average annual CO2 sequestration from negative emissions, scale-up of low-carbon primary energy share, final energy demand and carbon prices—show considerable variation across storylines (in this case the shared socioeconomic pathways47), even for a given model2. Such analysis also demonstrates that intermodel variation is comparably wide in many cases, so a multimodel assessment (even with one storyline) still usefully highlights the potential range of each feasibility indicator.

Table 2 List of applied feasibility indicators with relevant threshold data

A final consideration around feasibility is that the thresholds are not immutable laws—indeed, some historical cases prove that the chosen thresholds can be overcome. Two examples are the surge of gas-fired power in the Netherlands and nuclear power in France, which respectively surged from 5% to 80% and 25% to 75% of the power mix in one decade, surpassing the applied feasibility threshold in this study over tenfold. Since such historical examples of fast transitions are typically driven by public policy and support48, the feasibility analysis can also be interpreted as a mapping exercise of where policy support is strongly needed to overcome existing constraints, which is crucial for achieving stated climate targets as all models and scenarios in this study surpass several feasibility thresholds. Nevertheless, as the results show, this mapping strongly depends on the applied model: deep structural differences between models lead to a wide variety of pathways reaching the same climate targets and, hence, different policy interventions are necessary from different modelling perspectives to make these pathways feasible.

Discussion

Our results suggest that, if announced national near-term (2030) and longer-term (2050–2070) emissions reduction ambitions throughout the world are achieved, global peak temperature increase will stay below 2 °C with ~75% certainty. However, if climate action is not strengthened post-2030, long-term ambitions will not be achievable (long-term ratchet gap) and global temperature increase will be around or above 2 °C by 2100. All applied models agree that—with the current pace of policy implementation—temperature increase will not exceed 2.5 °C over the course of the century but will still have a rising trend thereafter. These results clearly show that climate action and ambitions have notably improved since 2020, when the same set of models and scenario structure projected 2030 emissions to be on average 3 GtCO2 higher (Extended Data Fig. 2) and mean global temperature 0.2–0.3 °C warmer by 210018. This improvement, alongside our finding that global emissions are set to peak in the current decade with current NDCs, is in line with earlier post-COP26 assessments22,23,24,27,28,29. The latter assessments, however, also found increasing emissions for current policy scenarios throughout and after the 2020s22,27,28,29, whereas all models in our study find reduction or stabilization of emissions with current policies within this decade. Furthermore, using a diverse set of different IAMs and thus covering a large part of structural uncertainty while reducing undesired model response heterogeneity, our study offers a more robust assessment of emissions and warming implications of post-Glasgow pledges and action, compared to these earlier single-model assessments.

Accounting for post-2030 extrapolations of current policies and NDCs, this study shows substantially lower emissions and end-of-century temperatures than other studies; additionally, our multimodel LTT projections are slightly more optimistic (by ~0.1 °C). An important reason for this difference probably lies in the applied extrapolation method: in contrast to a continued trend in emission intensities used in this study, other studies applied a carbon price equivalent to 2030 action and increasing over time with GDP levels23,27,28,29, a method leading to more conservative emissions reductions in most models18. There is no straightforward answer on which policy extrapolation method is better: while continuing a trend in emissions reductions may falsely bank on an emissions reduction trend that might not be equally attainable in the future, relying on extrapolated carbon prices may put too much faith in highly uncertain future model assumptions, especially considering that, for example, the decline in costs of low-carbon technologies have traditionally been underestimated in such assumptions12. Another important difference with several other model studies in the literature is that current policies are modelled explicitly (that is, not proxied via carbon prices until 2030; Supplementary Data) and on top of an up-to-date, harmonized set of socioeconomic and technoeconomic assumptions. This contributes to the relatively optimistic assessment of 2030 emissions in the study, as it endogenously assumes ratcheting of emissions reduction targets (by overperforming on these targets), where these are not ambitious.

Our scenario structure reflects three levels of ambition, where for each separate model region emissions are equal or lower with each subsequent level of ambition. Similarly, uncertainty to reach the modelled emissions reduction also increases with each subsequent level of ambition. Hence, despite aggregated national ambitions being in line with a temperature future well below 2 °C, the likelihood of all these national ambitions being achieved should not be overestimated. For each individual country that fails to meet its targets, the probability of higher temperature levels increases. Our feasibility analysis shows that, for most countries, it is far from straightforward to achieve their stated near- and long-term ambitions with the anticipated future demand patterns and technologies. The analysis reveals that there is no ‘free lunch’ in terms of feasibility of mitigation pathways: while different model structures imply heterogenous pathways to decarbonize economies in line with proposed pledges, each of the pathways compatible with a temperature future well below 2 °C faces substantial feasibility challenges, either in socioeconomic, technology scale-up, physical or sustainability dimensions. However, such feasibility challenges should not be interpreted as hard barriers to meet pledged mitigation targets but rather as areas where additional policy support or breakthroughs in technology or consumer behaviour49 may be needed to overcome such challenges.

Our results show that aggregating all national near- and long-term emissions reduction targets is still insufficient to limit global temperature increase to 1.5 °C (long-term ambition gap), which is the highest ambition of the Paris Agreement. Even if the most ambitious scenarios in this study are achieved, the temperature increase may still cause notable and damaging climate impacts50 and be sufficiently strong to activate several climate tipping elements, such as the collapse of the Greenland and West Antarctic ice sheet and the die-off of low-latitude coral reefs51,52. Therefore, even if ambitions have substantially improved in the run-up to and shortly after COP26, either cumulative emissions until 2050 must be reduced more to avoid overshooting the 1.5 °C target, or substantive negative emissions should be achieved after reaching LTTs to reach 1.5 °C by 2100 with a high overshoot (Extended Data Fig. 3). Nevertheless, the results of this study show that, while the focus on further ambition ratcheting should not be lost8, the short- and long-run implementation of the existing set of ambitions is currently the most relevant factor to avoid a climate disaster.

Methods

Models included

Four global IAMs are included in this research: GCAM-PR (also referred to as GCAM), GEMINI-E3 (also referred to as GEMINI), MUSE and TIAM-Grantham (also referred to as TIAM). These are selected to reflect the broad diversity of modelling theories, spanning a range from least-cost energy system optimization to partial and general equilibrium and to agent-based modelling. Diversity of modelling structure, theory and solution is typically sought in multimodel studies, aiming to reach robust estimates by reflecting structural uncertainty—rather than parametric uncertainty, which has been minimized to reduce unwanted response heterogeneity41.

GCAM54 is a partial equilibrium IAM, achieving equilibrium between energy supply and demand in each represented sector, accounting for the changes in energy prices resulting from changes in fuels and technologies used to satisfy energy-service demands in these sectors. The model operates on a ‘recursive dynamic’ cost-optimization basis and solves for the least-cost energy system (constrained by observed technological preferences) in a given period before moving onto the next period and performing the same process.

TIAM55 is also a partial equilibrium IAM and achieves similar equilibrium between energy supply and demand in each sector. However, TIAM operates on a ‘perfect foresight’ welfare cost-optimization basis, whereby all consequences of technology deployments, fuel extraction and energy price changes over the entire time horizon are considered when minimizing the cost of the energy system to provide energy-service demands within specified emissions constraints.

GEMINI-E3 (ref. 56) differs in model solution in that it is a general equilibrium IAM, featuring a more detailed, multiple-sector representation of the economy that considers how the impacts of specific policies spread across economic sectors and regions affect environmental parameters. This means that, despite also being driven by market equilibrium, this equilibrium is assumed to take place simultaneously in each market/region. Its richer representation of the economy requires calibration to data on national and international socio-accounting information and a vector of various elasticities of substitution but it allows endogenous calculation of market prices of inputs and outputs.

Finally, MUSE57 is an agent-based, energy system model that provides a detailed account of the energy sector to calculate least-cost GHG emissions reduction pathways—or the costs of alternative climate policies. It is bottom-up, in that it assumes short-term microeconomic equilibrium on the energy system by iterating market clearance across all sector modules and interchanging price and quantity of each energy commodity in each region but it is also agent-based, in that it tries to determine a mitigation pathway by providing an as-realistic-as-possible description of the investment and operational decision-making in each geographical region within a sector.

All four models differ in the way technologies are chosen across sectors: GCAM uses a logit technology choice mechanism, which causes gradually decreasing returns as a technology is further diffused; TIAM uses a winner-takes-all optimization mechanism, implying that the cheapest technology can dominate all new deployment; GEMINI uses a nested constant elasticity of substitution function; while MUSE follows an agent-based approach, where agent decision goals and strategies determine technology choices in each time step. Detailed model documentation for all four models is available online at https://www.i2am-paris.eu/detailed_model_doc.

Scenario protocol

Starting this modelling exercise, harmonized socioeconomic and technoeconomic input assumptions were applied by all models, reflecting the latest available information and avoiding ‘noise’ in the model outcomes related to unaligned assumptions41. For GDP projections, the IMF WEO of April 202258 for GDP growth until 2027 the OECD EO-109 (2021)59 for post-2027 growth projections, reflecting the impacts of the COVID-19 pandemic as well as initial estimated impacts related to the Ukraine conflict. On technoeconomic assumptions, power generation technology costs were updated to observed 2020 values (IRENA) while maintaining the future evolution of costs as reflected in ref. 41. For hydrogen, projections of different production technologies were updated according to IEA estimates (2017)60. It should be noted that, despite considerable efforts to harmonize model inputs, the four IAMs do not all represent the same portfolio of technologies; this hampers the efforts of reducing unwanted heterogeneity of responses and of attributing the resulting model spread only to structural uncertainty. However, our multimodel assessment remains useful in that it provides an implicit assessment of the variety of pathways that could result not just from structural differences but also from different assumptions around the availability of key technologies (for example, direct air capture61,62).

The first scenario (Current Policy extrapolated with EI, CP_EI) is based on the current portfolio of actual emissions reduction policies as well as credible policy targets until 2030 in G20 countries including the entire EU (Supplementary Data). Post-2030 action is then modelled by measuring the average rate of change in emissions intensity of GDP from 2020 to 2030 in each region and assuming emissions-intensity reduction rates will remain the same after 2030. This method is also used by refs. 18,22,15 to assess the long-term implications of NDCs. The applied policy targets until 2030 (for example, renewable energy mix targets, vehicle fuel standards) are maintained as minimum levels beyond 2030 to avoid backtracking of achieved policies.

The second scenario (NDCs extrapolated with EI, NDC_EI) is based on stated 2030 emission targets captured in NDCs submitted or announced by June 2022, capturing all mitigation ambition updates related to the COP26 in Glasgow (Supplementary Table 1). These NDC targets are applied on top of current policies (CP) modelled in the previous scenario; in model regions where current policies overachieve on the mitigation targets in NDCs, no additional emission constraints are applied, following ref. 18. Emissions reductions in NDC scenarios are therefore never less ambitious than what CP implies. The same EI method is applied for post-2030 action as in CP_EI.

The third and most ambitious scenario (NDCs with LTTs, NDC_LTT) is built on the NDC_EI until 2030 but, for regions that expressed an LTT, such as net-zero commitments or other targets for 2050 or later (either in law, policy documents or only announced) (Supplementary Table 2), emission constraints are applied that linearly decline from 2030 emissions as in the NDC_EI scenario towards said long-term target. For regions without LTTs, post-2030 emissions follow an identical path as in the NDC_EI scenario.

Since nearly all countries have submitted at least some NDC target, defining NDC targets for aggregated model regions is relatively straightforward. However, far from all countries have submitted LTTs, hence some assumptions are required if one or more countries in an aggregated model region have LTTs. In such cases, the emissions level (E) should be calculated by applying the LTT to the estimated emissions share of that specific country (i) in the entire model region (j) according to either the 2019 emissions levels53 or, if available, the country´s emissions share in the aggregated NDC target for 2030 and applying the EI method for the rest of the region:

$$\begin{array}{rcl}{E_{j,2050}} &= &{E\left( {\mathrm{LTT}} \right)_{i,2050} \times \left( {\frac{{E_{i,2019/2030}}}{{E_{j,2019/2030}}}} \right)} \\&&+ E\left( {\mathrm{EI}} \right)_{j - i,2050} \times \left( {\frac{{\left( {E_{j,2019/2030} - E_{i,2019/2030}} \right)}}{{E_{j,2019/2030}}}} \right)\end{array}$$

Temperature assessment

To assess the implications of the modelled scenarios for global mean temperature increase, emission outcomes from the models are harmonized with historical tendencies, infilled to include the full set of GHG emissions and fed into a climate model for probabilistic temperature simulations.

In most instances, the first stage of the temperature assessment is to harmonize the global emissions trajectories to known values in 2015 (interpolated if not already present) using ratio-based harmonization approach63. Since not all models report the entire set of GHGs and other pollutants required for a complete temperature assessment, unreported emissions from each model participating in this intermodal comparison exercise are infilled using Silicone v.1.3.0 (ref. 64), using a quantile rolling window with CO2 emissions from energy and industrial processes as the lead emissions and based on an infilling database comprised of the harmonized AR6 database65 filtered to match the model philosophy. The models that are included in the AR6 database are categorized on the basis of their model type (for example, general equilibrium/partial equilibrium) and solution type (recursive dynamics/intertemporal). The exception to this is the F-gases (SF6, HFCs and PFCs), which are not reported by enough models in each category. For these cases (where not reported otherwise), we use the F-gas total infilled as above, then break it down into its component SF6, HFC total and PFC total using the whole harmonized AR6 database and the Silicone technique DecomposeCollectionTimeDepRatio. For the GEMINI-E3 model simulating global economy dynamics over the time horizon 2015 to 2050, we extend each of the emissions until 2100 for each scenario using the Silicone tool ExtendLatestTimeQuantile, using the whole AR6 database. Plotting the infilled trajectories of Kyoto gases instead of fossil CO2 produces very similar results, as fossil CO2 correlates well with the Kyoto gas total in the AR6 database (Supplementary Fig. 3) and our infilling technique preserves the correlation between the modelled gas and all the constituents.

When we have a complete set of required emissions, they are run through the simple climate model FaIR v.1.6.2, calibrated to match the AR6 Working Group 1 climate assessment66,67. This four-box model of the world replicates the impact of emissions on atmospheric concentrations, climate forcings and temperatures, constrained both against observations and the probability distributions of fundamental climate characteristics like transient climate response assessed by the IPCC.

Supplementary Fig. 4 shows the median temperature assessments until 2100 from FaIR, while also showing the uncertainty in this temperature assessment related to infilling the emission trajectories using silicone.

Climate action gap definition

Comparing scenario outcomes allows us to subdivide the climate action gap—that is, the difference between the emissions reductions and related temperature outcomes that can be expected with the current set of policies in all countries, with the goal of keeping global temperature increase below 1.5 °C. It is with these two trajectories (current policies as in ‘where we stand’ and 1.5 °C as in ‘where we want to go’) and the two intermediate trajectories (NDCs as in ‘ambition reflected in near-term targets’ and LTTs as in ‘ambition reflected in long-term targets’) that we define the different gaps in this study. The first gap, hereby termed ‘implementation gap’, refers to the difference in 2100 or peak temperature (depending on whether a peak is reached in the twenty-first century) of current policies and that of 2030 NDCs, both extended by EI trends. The second gap, hereby termed ‘long-term ratchet gap’, refers to the temperature difference between the 2030 NDCs extended by EI trends, on the one hand and the 2030 NDCs followed by LTTs (where stated), on the other—in other words, it refers to the pace, in which post-2030 action must be accelerated relative to pre-2030 action to deliver on LTTs. The final gap, hereby termed ‘ambition gap’, refers to the difference between the peak temperature of 2030 NDCs followed by available LTTs and the 1.5 °C target. These three gaps, altogether making up the climate action gap, are illustrated in detail in Fig. 1 and are not to be confused with the United Nations Environment Programme definition of ‘emissions gap’19; the latter refers to the emissions difference between the promised reductions (as in NDCs and/or LTTs) and the needed reductions (as in least-cost pathways delivering 1.5 °C), which we do not calculate.

Feasibility assessment

This study looks into the feasibility of pathways based on country-specific policies and announced targets, with the objective to identify ‘where’ (which country and sector) and ‘when’ (which decade between 2020 and 2050) we find the largest bottlenecks to achieving them. This feasibility analysis builds largely on the framework of ref. 38, measuring feasibility concerns by comparing specific model outcomes with threshold values found in the literature. It also defines feasibility as in that framework, that is, as the degree to which a scenario lies within the boundaries of diverse societal capacities for change in a given period. However, the reflected dimensions are largely constrained by the capacity to quantify with all models used in this study, while overlapping dimensions are avoided to allow a fair comparison of feasibility concerns between models.

The feasibility analysis looks at specific variables in model outcomes and compares these with several thresholds found in literature. A total of ten different feasibility indicators are measured, which can be divided into three categories: (1) socioeconomic feasibility concerns related with the cost burden of mitigation policies, (2) technology scale-up feasibility concerns related with the velocity at which clean technologies replace existing technologies in place and (3) physical feasibility constraints related with the physical potentials for bioenergy production and carbon storage. Therefore, our analysis does not include bottom-up sociopolitical dimensions that cannot be quantified in (all) our models and our definition of feasibility should not be interpreted as broadly as defined in literature68,69 but defined by the modelled dimensions considered—hence, we discuss ‘feasibility concerns’ rather than feasibility.

Feasibility concerns are measured by model region and 10-year period (2020–2030, 2030–2040 and 2040–2050) to illustrate ‘where’ and ‘when’ we find the largest bottlenecks to climate change mitigation. Identically for all indicators, a value of the size of 1 represents that the specific threshold for that indicator is surpassed by 100% in that specific model region and period. Similarly, scores of 0.5 and 1.5 mean surpassing the thresholds by, respectively, 50% and 150%. That also means that, as long as the threshold is not passed, even if it comes close, the feasibility concern is measured as zero. Similarly for all indicators, the global value is built up as a weighted average of the independent values in all model regions. The weighting variable, however, varies between the different indicators (Table 2). For more details on how the different feasibility indicators are approached, on the precise threshold levels as well as the sources these levels are taken from, see Supplementary Section 2. For the precise feasibility concern levels under centrally assumed threshold as well as under threshold uncertainty (Fig. 3b), see Source Data for Figs. 3 and 4.

Reporting summary

Further information on research design is available in the Nature Portfolio Reporting Summary linked to this article.